Total Pageviews

Thursday, November 28, 2013

Reducing the Impact of Too Big to Fail

Phillip Swagel is a professor at the School of Public Policy at the University of Maryland and was assistant secretary for economic policy at the Treasury Department from 2006 to 2009.

In the years leading up to the financial crisis, market participants assumed that policy makers would intervene to avoid the potential negative economic impact from the failure of a systemically important bank. As William C. Dudley, the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, discussed in a recent speech, the belief that some companies were too big to be allowed to fail gave rise to a variety of problems, notably including a situation of moral hazard that encouraged risky bets by market participants who figured they could keep the upside but have their losses covered by taxpayers.

And indeed, when things went wrong during the crisis, the interventions materialized, as detailed in a recent report by the Government Accountability Office.

The Dodd-Frank financial regulatory reform law of 2010 and regulatory changes since the crisis have affected the incentives for both companies and investors, but it is too soon to say that the advantages and risks of large banks have been addressed or that the era of too big to fail is over. We will not really know until the next time a large bank is on the verge of collapse.

In the meantime, one way to glean information on whether investor perceptions of the potential for future bailouts have changed is to compare the funding costs of large banks relative to small banks.

In an insightful new paper, Randall S. Kroszner of the University of Chicago’s Booth School of Business, a former governor of the Federal Reserve, does just that. Professor Kroszner’s paper was supported by the Clearing House Association, an organization of large banks (I was a member of the association’s now-defunct academic advisory council and a former colleague of Professor Kroszner’s when he served as a member appointed by President George W. Bush at the White House Council of Economic Advisers, but was not involved in the preparation or review of his research).

Professor Kroszner reviews a variety of evidence that suggests that one manifestation of too big to fail before the financial crisis was that large banks could obtain funds with which to make loans and other investments at a lower cost than smaller companies whose demise would not motivate an extraordinary government response.

Not every piece of evidence fits this conclusion - it could be the case, for example, that large companies in every industry have lower costs than smaller ones - and estimates of the magnitude of the pre-crisis funding advantage differ across studies. But the overall conclusion that large banks had a funding advantage suggests an implicit government subsidy from the expectation of government action to support large banks.

Perhaps the best-known effort to quantify this support is the calculation by the editors of Bloomberg View of an $83 billion annual subsidy to the 10 largest United States banks, reflecting a supposed funding advantage of around 0.8 percentage points from the implicit government support multiplied by those companies’ huge liabilities (that is, the money with which they fund their activities).

Small banks tend to rely on deposits for their funding, along with advances from the Federal Home Loan Banks to support mortgage lending; larger institutions rely more heavily on bonds and other capital market sources. There is moral hazard involved with banks of all sizes, because deposits are covered by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, which means that most depositors know that they will not take losses if a bank fails.

But this insurance is explicit and paid for, as opposed to the after-the-fact and unpaid bailout received by bondholders who did not suffer losses because of government interventions.

In a sense, the most unfair bailouts during the crisis were not of banks themselves, but of their bondholders - the investors who provided the funding for the bad lending decisions. Shareholders at Bear Stearns, Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac and the American International Group took sizable losses, but the owners of the bonds of these companies received 100 cents on the dollar as a result of government actions to stabilize the financial system. As I have written elsewhere, these actions were necessary and appropriate, but bailouts nonetheless.

Three important changes made since the financial crisis affect the funding costs of large banks in a way that suggests a reduced government subsidy and a move toward a level playing field with institutions that are not viewed as too big to fail.

The first change is that the resolution authority in Title II of Dodd-Frank gives government officials the power to take over troubled large financial companies and impose losses on bondholders and other funders in a way that was not previously possible. (Until the advent of the Troubled Asset Relief Program, or TARP, the power to stabilize failing companies was limited to the bank subsidiaries of large financial companies but did not encompass other components such as broker-dealers; government officials thus did not have the authority to take over Lehman Brothers, for example.)

Indeed, Title II requires that any losses from a future government intervention must be borne by private market participants, including bondholders.

Investors contemplating the purchase of large bank bonds should understand that they will take losses rather than get a guarantee in the next crisis. This, in turn, should affect funding costs in normal times and reduce the advantage of large banks. It is hard to know if the resolution authority will work as planned (the government agencies involved are still devising the rules), but there is some evidence that the advent of the new law has reduced the perceived likelihood of future bailouts. As Professor Kroszner notes, the three major credit ratings agencies cite the resolution authority as a factor behind their view of a lower likelihood of future government support for large banks.

The second change is that banks must now pay insurance premiums to the F.D.I.C. on their nondeposit sources of funds, even though these borrowings are not covered by the federal guarantee and would take losses under Dodd-Frank Title II. The idea is that deposits tend to be more stable than bonds and other capital market borrowings, so charging banks for using these latter sources of funds provides an incentive against financial system volatility. With large banks the heaviest users of such borrowed money, this effectively moves in the direction of a level playing field with smaller banks.

Finally, the largest banks are required to fund themselves with more capital than smaller banks under the Basel III capital rules and to maintain larger amounts of readily liquid assets. These provisions reflect the desire by policy makers to strengthen the ability of systemically important financial institutions to withstand losses, including in a future financial crisis.

Capital surcharges and heightened liquidity requirements for large banks improve the stability of the financial system, while again moving in the direction of less support for large banks and increased costs relative to smaller ones.

There is evidence that the new regulations are making a difference. An analysis of stock market returns and the cost to insure bank bonds against default indicates that major steps forward in devising financial regulations, such as the Volcker Rule in the United States, resulted in reduced market expectations of future bailouts.

Bond investors, for example, required more compensation to lend to banks as the Dodd-Frank reforms moved forward, with the impact greater for large banks than small banks. In contrast, there was little effect from German financial reforms that were widely seen as ineffective. Bond markets appear to be paying attention to the implications of financial regulatory reform.

It is too soon to say that the changes put in place after the crisis have ended the expectation of government bailouts and the extent to which these changes reduced any implicit support for the activities of large banks.

Still, the situation has changed. The funding advantage of large banks over smaller ones used in the calculation of subsidies by Bloomberg and others is taken from data before the 2010 Dodd-Frank financial regulatory reform and other changes made in the wake of the crisis. Updated analysis would be useful to assess the impact of the post-crisis measures. Professor Kroszner’s paper provides recommendations for future researchers.

Government actions taken during the financial crisis to support large banks were important for stabilizing the financial system and supporting the overall economy. In other words, saving Wall Street was necessary to save Main Street. But the way in which this happened was a source of understandably deep frustration to many Americans (including to the policy makers who undertook the interventions). Reforms made since the crisis have changed the situation.

It is important now to evaluate just how much change has been made. This is a key requirement to know whether more steps are needed.



Getting the Volcker Rule Done

DESCRIPTION

Simon Johnson, former chief economist of the International Monetary Fund, is the Ronald A. Kurtz Professor of Entrepreneurship at the M.I.T. Sloan School of Management and co-author of “White House Burning: The Founding Fathers, Our National Debt, and Why It Matters to You.”

Paul Volcker, former chairman of the Federal Reserve, has pressed forcefully for curbs on the biggest banks.Mike Segar/Reuters Paul Volcker, former chairman of the Federal Reserve, has pressed forcefully for curbs on the biggest banks.

December is deadline time for one of the most important unfinished pieces of businesses from the Dodd-Frank financial reform legislation: the Volcker Rule. Based on an important intervention by Paul A. Volcker, the former chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, in late 2009, the “rule,” whose legal intent is enshrined in Dodd-Frank, is simple - end proprietary trading by very large banks.

“Proprietary trading” is the business of betting, using the bank’s own funds, on the direction of markets. When these bets go well, traders and executives are very well paid through bonuses and other mechanisms. But when even a few mega-bets go badly (think mortgage-backed securities), there is a big potential downside risk to the economy, including damage to the bank’s ability to conduct all its ordinary activities (such as making loans to the non-financial sector).

The rule takes aim at the five largest complex financial companies, which have an implicit government backstop as well as insurance from the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation for their retail deposits. This arrangement presumably encourages reckless risk-taking, including proprietary trading.

The big bank lobby has been fighting hard against any version of the Volcker Rule since it was first proposed. They have lost some important battles but remain determined to make one last-ditch stand, focusing on the argument that the rule should be further delayed. But delay in this kind of situation rarely leads to a better or stronger regulation.

It’s time to get the Volcker Rule done properly - and that means in line with what Mr. Volcker originally proposed and what the Democratic senators Jeff Merkley of Oregon and Carl Levin of Michigan put into legislative language.

(Mr. Volcker and I both take part in the Systemic Risk Council, founded and headed by Sheila Bair, former chairwoman of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. The views expressed here are mine alone.)

There are three arguments still put forward by big banks and their advocates.

First, they assert that the rule is not needed, because proprietary trading was not a major cause of the crisis of 2007-8.

This point is irrelevant; we should always worry about what may happen in the future, not what happened in the past. It is also wrong. Remember, too, that the losses at Bear Stearns, Lehman Brothers, Merrill Lynch, Morgan Stanley and UBS were in no small due to forms of proprietary trading; Citigroup also springs to mind. I testified to the Senate Banking Committee in early 2010 in favor of the rule; John Reed, the former chief executive of Citigroup, was on the same side. We were opposed by the chief risk officer of JPMorgan Chase, among others.

Subsequently, JPMorgan Chase suffered big losses in a proprietary bet that has become known as the London Whale.

That these trades did not bring down JPMorgan Chase is not reassuring. Those losses and the way they were misunderstood or misrepresented by management are like a canary in the coal mine - telling you there is trouble ahead. When the canary dies from gas poisoning, the smart response is not, “Well, only the canary is dead, so let’s carry on with what we are doing.”

Second, some big bank advocates contend that they should be allowed so-called “macro hedging” or “portfolio hedging.” This is a dangerous idea, because in effect they are asking for the right to do any trade they want and - ex post - assert this is hedging for some part of the portfolio.

A much better approach, and hopefully where we are headed, is to allow hedging only for specific, measurable risks. The hedges would need to be identified when the trade is done; presumably this is part of the risk control and management reporting already. (Properly defined, “hedging” refers to the practice of trying to offset the risk in one transaction by undertaking another transaction that should be negatively correlated - i.e., when the value of one trade or asset goes down, the value of its hedge goes up.)

Third is a vague but potentially dangerous argument that various forms of financial regulation should be delayed until we can more fully converge with the Europeans and their planned rules.

As Jeffrey Schott and I explained in a recent paper on the potential free trade agreement with Europe, any version of this would be a bad idea.

There are many theories for why the Volcker Rule has taken so long to enact, including intentionally slow work by the staff of the Federal Reserve Board, divisions among members of the Securities and Exchange Commission and pushback from Europeans.

None of this matters today. As Treasury Secretary Jacob J. Lew said in July, “We will not let the pursuit of international consistency force us to lower our standards.”

The goal should be to complete the existing pipeline of reforms and then assess properly where we are. Again, Mr. Lew got this right when he said, “If we get to the end of this year and we cannot, with an honest, straight face, say that we have ended too big to fail, we are going to have to look at other options.”

Everyone working on the Volcker Rule should be held accountable to this high but entirely reasonable standard. Then we can assess the extent to which the problem of some banks’ being too big to fail is still with us - and what we should do about it.



Wednesday, November 27, 2013

Changing Assistance for the Unemployed

DESCRIPTION

Casey B. Mulligan is an economics professor at the University of Chicago. He is the author of “The Redistribution Recession: How Labor Market Distortions Contracted the Economy.”

Even if federal unemployment insurance expires at the end of the year, it will be replaced by an even more generous assistance program for people leaving their jobs.

Unemployment insurance is jointly administered and financed by federal and state governments, offering funds to “covered” people who lost their jobs and have as yet been unable to find and start a new one. The cash assistance comes weekly, with states paying benefits of about $300 a week for 26 weeks or until the person starts a new job, whichever comes first.

Normally, the assistance stops after 26 weeks, even if the beneficiary has yet to find a job. But during recessions the federal government’s temporary “extended” and “emergency” unemployment compensation programs pick up benefits after the state benefits are exhausted.

During the recent recession, the federal government paid benefits for up to 73 additional weeks, making the total benefit duration 99 weeks.

The temporary federal programs have expiration dates, but Congress has routinely extended them, at least through 2012. A couple of the federal programs fully expired that year, so in 2013 the unemployed could get benefits for no longer than 73 weeks.

The last remaining federal program, known as Emergency Unemployment Compensation, is set to fully expire at the end of this year. Congress has extended its final expiration date several times in the past - most recently as part of the fiscal cliff deal - but there is no guarantee that Congress will continue its extensions.

If the emergency program continues while the new health care assistance comes on line, the incentives of workers and employers to create and retain jobs will take a big hit. The solid line in the chart below shows my estimates of the average marginal tax rate on worker’s income, accounting for the fact that earning income on a job results in both additional taxes and withheld federal benefits. The higher the tax rate, the less is the incentive to work.

Casey B. Mulligan's estimates of the impact of emergency unemployment compensation ending in December 2013. Casey B. Mulligan’s estimates of the impact of emergency unemployment compensation ending in December 2013.

The dashed line shows the marginal tax rate if the emergency program really does expire at the end of the year. Tax rates will increase in January, but much less than they would without the expiration, because the assistance lost from the emergency program will be offset by the health assistance coming online.

The federal unemployment benefits at risk of expiration are economically more important than the already-expired programs, because it is less common for unemployment to last more than 73 weeks (when the expired programs kicked in) than it is to last 26.

Unemployment benefits from any program help people who desperately need it, but they also keep the labor market depressed by permitting people to remain unemployed longer and making layoffs more common. The remaining emergency program is the most important and thereby does the most to help people and the most to keep the labor market depressed.

Even if the emergency program is allowed to expire on Jan. 1, it will ‘be replaced by an even larger program â€" the Affordable Care Act â€" assisting the unemployed and others, including premium subsidies for health insurance.

Most people have jobs that provide health insurance and will be ineligible for premium subsidies for as long as they work. But as soon as they are fired, quit, retire or otherwise leave the payroll, they will be eligible for monthly assistance to pay for their health insurance premiums and out-of-pocket expenses.

For households between 100 and 400 percent of the poverty line - that’s about half of households - the new assistance will average about $110 a week, tax free (unlike unemployment benefits, which are taxable). Moreover, the premium assistance is not limited to 26 weeks; it can last for decades.

Regardless of how you evaluate the relative costs and benefits of the emergency program, now is the time for Emergency Unemployment Compensation to expire to make way for new assistance programs.



Monday, November 25, 2013

Effective Corporate Tax Rates

DESCRIPTION

Bruce Bartlett held senior policy roles in the Reagan and George H.W. Bush administrations and served on the staffs of Representatives Jack Kemp and Ron Paul. He is the author of “The Benefit and the Burden: Tax Reform â€" Why We Need It and What It Will Take.”

Although the prospects for tax reform in Congress have dimmed of late, the lobbying activity has not. The corporate community continues to put pressure on Congress to reduce the statutory corporate tax rate, which, at 39.1 percent including state and local taxes, is the highest among members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.

What tends to get lost in the debate is how much corporations actually pay in taxes once various deductions and credits are taken into account. A corporation’s total tax bill divided by its profits is its effective tax rate. It’s hard to imagine a corporation paying anywhere close to 39 percent of all its profits in taxes, as that would mean it has no deductions or credits whatsoever.

According to the Internal Revenue Service, corporations had gross profits of $1.8 trillion in 2007 and taxable income of $1.2 trillion. Since the Tax Reform Act of 1986, new corporate tax preferences have widened the gap between gross income and taxable income. In 1987, gross corporate profits reported on tax returns were $328 billion and taxable income was $312 billion. Thus since 1987, taxable income has fallen to 68 percent from 95 percent of gross income.

Of course, many corporations are so adept at manipulating the tax code that they pay no federal taxes at all. According to Citizens for Tax Justice, a progressive group, 78 companies paid no federal income taxes at least one year between 2008 and 2010. The data come from annual company reports and may not necessarily reflect actual tax payments on tax returns because of different accounting concepts.

Earlier this year, the Government Accountability Office, a federal agency, examined corporate tax returns to determine the taxes corporations actually pay. It found that in 2010, profitable corporations based in the United States had an effective federal tax rate of 13 percent on their worldwide income, 17 percent including state and local taxes.

The following chart shows corporate profits as a share of the gross domestic product. As one can see, 2010 was a good year, with profits very close to their pre-recession level and about a third higher than the boom years of the 1990s. Since 2010, profits have increased by another percentage point of G.D.P.

Shaded areas indicate recessions in the United States.Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Shaded areas indicate recessions in the United States.

But aggregate corporate taxes in 2010 were low, just 1.3 percent of G.D.P., because corporations can carry forward losses from previous years to offset taxes in future years. Since many corporations had huge losses in 2008 and 2009, because of the economic recession, this reduced their tax liability in 2010 below the long-term trend of about 2 percent of G.D.P.

The corporate community was upset by the G.A.O. study because it undercut its campaign to cut the corporate tax rate. On Oct. 26, Andrew B. Lyon, a PricewaterhouseCoopers economist who served as deputy assistant secretary of the Treasury for tax analysis during the George W. Bush administration, published a study criticizing the G.A.O. analysis. (The study was posted on the website of an organization, the Alliance for Competitive Taxation, that represents many of the largest and most profitable companies in America and lobbies to cut the federal corporate tax rate to 25 percent from 35 percent.)

Mr. Lyon’s study found that the G.A.O. had understated the corporate tax burden by focusing on a single anomalous year, excluding foreign taxes paid and not including companies that had losses; the G.A.O. study looked only at profitable corporations. His estimate put the effective corporate tax rate at 36.2 percent - above the statutory rate.

The exclusion of foreign taxes is not significant, because American companies get a 100 percent credit for all foreign taxes paid against their tax liability in the United States. Including companies with losses raises the aggregate effective tax rate by reducing aggregate profits. Thus the losses of those that paid no taxes are in effect attributed to profitable companies, making their tax burden appear higher by shrinking their measured profits while their taxes are unchanged.

The independent economist Martin A. Sullivan concluded that the truth is somewhere in between, with the effective corporate tax rate in the mid to upper 20 percent range. In the Nov. 25 issue of Tax Notes magazine, the G.A.O. economists who conducted the original study acknowledged that averaging their results over several years and including foreign taxes, as Mr. Lyon did, would raise the effective tax rate to 22.9 percent. The remaining difference between their study and the Lyon study results from the inclusion of companies with losses.

The debate is highly technical, involving accounting concepts on which there is legitimate discussion. There is also a data problem, because corporate tax returns are private, just as individual returns are. But some analysts, such as the Reuters columnist Felix Salmon, assert that public corporations ought to be required to make their returns available because they contain information that investors have a legitimate right to have. It might also shame a few of the more aggressive corporate tax avoiders into being a little less aggressive.

A key element of the debate over cutting the corporate tax rate is how the United States compares with other countries when corporations decide where to invest and realize profits for tax purposes. Under American law, multinational corporations based in the United States are not taxed on profits earned in foreign countries until those profits are repatriated to the United States. It is estimated that upward of $2 trillion in profits are in effect sitting abroad, unavailable either to shareholders as dividends or to be taxed by the Treasury.

On Nov. 19, Senator Max Baucus, Democrat of Montana and chairman of the Senate Finance Committee, released a proposed reform of international corporate taxation. It would tax foreign profits as earned and end deferral. Previously deferred profits would be subject to a 20 percent tax rate. Writing in The New York Times, Victor Fleischer, a professor at the University of San Diego law school, saw merit in the Baucus plan but noted that it differs sharply from one previously put forward by Representative Dave Camp, Republican of Michigan and chairman of the House Ways and Means Committee.

The path to corporate tax reform is not yet clear, but it’s useful to have two substantive proposals on the table. Regardless of how the effective corporate tax rate is calculated, it’s a bad idea to encourage companies to hold their profits abroad simply because the tax code makes it lucrative to do so.



Less Need to Worry About Inflation

Jared Bernstein is a senior fellow at the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities in Washington and a former chief economist to Vice President Joseph R. Biden Jr.

Last week, Dean Baker and I asserted on this blog that the Phillips Curve has flattened over the years, and this development means policy makers face a diminished risk of inflation in the pursuit of full employment.

This week, I’d like to unpack that very dense sentence.

First, what’s the Phillips Curve (and who was Phillips)? For one, he was a Kiwi, one of a line now including the great New Zealand economists Julia Lane and Chye-Ching Huang (to name only the ones I personally know). The Phillips Curve is a negatively sloping line in a graph with wage or price growth on the Y axis and unemployment on the X axis. The more slack in the job market, the less pressure we expect on wage growth and thus price growth.

Now, when you think unemployment/inflation trade-off, you are likely to think of the Federal Reserve. When its governors ply monetary policy to lower unemployment, as they’re doing today, they typically worry about pushing too far and generating inflation. The Phillips Curve tells them how much to worry, i.e., how much they would expect inflation to accelerate for each percentage point reduction in unemployment.

We’ll get to the main event - the flattening of the curve - in a moment, but first we need to dive a bit deeper into the Phillips Curve weeds. The equation below is one way economists think of the curve these days, and it will help in our analysis of how it has changed over time.

inf = inf_exp - K x (U-U*)

Inflation (inf in the equation) today is a function of expected inflation minus the slope of the curve (that’s the “K,” for Kiwi) times the unemployment gap, a measure of labor market slack defined by the actual unemployment rate minus the full employment rate. Each one of those terms to the right of the equal sign has evolved in important ways.

First, it is widely believed that inflationary expectations have become increasingly well-anchored. The Fed has convinced people that inflation will generally flit about its target rate of 2 percent. That doesn’t mean the Fed can stop a price spike resulting from some supply shock or other, like a disruption to the oil supply. But the expectation is embedded in the system such that once the temporary shock is resolved, inflation will settle back to its expected rate.

Second, K, the negative slope of the Phillips Curve, has drifted up toward zero. My own estimate is shown below in the solid line, using the same method as in this important paper by Laurence Ball and Sandeep Mazumder.

Author's estimation of Equation (3) in “Inflation Dynamics and the Great Recession,” by Laurence Ball and Sandeep Mazumder (link above), as in their Figure 3b.  Author used the personal consumption expenditures core inflation measure as opposed to the consumer price index core used in their paper. The dotted lines represent two standard errors. Author’s estimation of Equation (3) in “Inflation Dynamics and the Great Recession,” by Laurence Ball and Sandeep Mazumder (link above), as in their Figure 3b.  Author used the personal consumption expenditures core inflation measure as opposed to the consumer price index core used in their paper. The dotted lines represent two standard errors.

Clearly, K has moved around over time, posting the biggest negatives in the 1970s, when inflation was buffeted about by supply shocks and poorly anchored. In fact, the 1970s is the only period wherein the standard error lines do not cross zero, suggesting the slope has actually been hard to identify with precision for most of its recent life.

Most recently, K by this estimate has been around zero. If that were true, and I don’t think it is, there would be no trade-off at all. But as Dean Baker and I wrote last week, “The fact that inflation has grown less responsive to lower unemployment means the weighting of the risks associated with the unemployment-inflation trade-off has changed in favor of full employment.”

True, one could assert that a flatter curve actually makes it harder for the Fed to reduce price pressures through higher unemployment, but I don’t think that’s a problem. In fact, along with the stronger anchoring function, numerous other factors are probably reducing inflation these days, including the increased supply of goods courtesy of globalization and sticky nominal wages. The Phillips Curve is a stalwart macroeconomic war horse, but it’s an awfully simple, if not reductionist, construct.

One last point. There’s something important and interesting going on with the last part of that equation above. First, U (the unemployment rate) is biased down because so many people have dropped out of the labor force, meaning the actual unemployment gap is larger than the measured one and implying that the labor market is probably putting more downward pressure on prices than we thought (and suggesting that the Fed should lower its unemployment target accordingly).

Second, and this pushes the other way (i.e., toward a smaller unemployment gap), the share of the unemployed who are long-termers is higher than it has ever been, and this too plays out in the Phillips Curve. A fundamental relation behind the curve is that as more unemployed unsuccessfully search for work, wage and price pressures diminish. But other research finds that the longer you’re unemployed, the less intense is your job search, so these folks may have little impact on wage pressure.

The interesting point about this right now is that if you ran an equation like the one above on today’s data, you might expect deflation. One reason we’re not there may be because all those long-termers raise the unemployment rate but don’t put much downward pressure on wages and prices.

The key conclusion is that the trade-off between unemployment and inflation is a lot less steep than it used to be, inflationary expectations are well-anchored and, even in good times, most workers these days have little bargaining power. That’s one reason they’re seeing so few gains from a recovery that’s a lot more evident on Wall Street than on Main Street.

So policy makers should seriously down-weight the phantom menace of inflation. Even if they overshoot on the unemployment side, an extremely unlikely result in today’s policy climate, the impact on prices is likely to be minimal.



Young and Uninsured, in Charts

Last week, the Census Bureau released some nice charts about the young and uninsured â€" that is, the folks that insurance companies are now falling over themselves to sign up because young people are cheap (and can be charged premiums higher than are actuarially fair in order to subsidize older people).

Here’s a chart showing that in 2012, adults age 19 to 34 years old had the highest uninsured rates of any other age group (26.9 percent):

Census Bureau


According to the bureau, there were 18 million uninsured 19- to 34-year-olds in 2012, who accounted for 40 percent of the total uninsured population under the age of 65. The uninsured rate has fallen in recent years for Americans age 19 to 25, however, thanks to a 2010 policy change that allows dependents to remain on their parents’ health insurance plan until their 26th birthday.

Percent uninsured, 2008-2012, based on American Community Survey data.Census Bureau Percent uninsured, 2008-2012, based on American Community Survey data.

There’s huge variation around the country, with the uninsured rate of young adults ranging from about 7.8 percent in Massachusetts and the District of Columbia to 38.7 percent in Texas.

Map reflects uninsured rates for adults age 19 to 34 years old by state.Census Bureau Map reflects uninsured rates for adults age 19 to 34 years old by state.

Of the largest metro areas in the country, the uninsured rate for younger Americans was lowest in Boston-Cambridge-Quincy, Mass., and New Hampshire, at 7.9 percent, and was highest in Miami-Fort Lauderdale-Pompano Beach, Fla., at 41 percent.



Young and Uninsured, in Charts

Last week, the Census Bureau released some nice charts about the young and uninsured â€" that is, the folks that insurance companies are now falling over themselves to sign up because young people are cheap (and can be charged premiums higher than are actuarially fair in order to subsidize older people).

Here’s a chart showing that in 2012, adults age 19 to 34 years old had the highest uninsured rates of any other age group (26.9 percent):

Census Bureau


According to the bureau, there were 18 million uninsured 19- to 34-year-olds in 2012, who accounted for 40 percent of the total uninsured population under the age of 65. The uninsured rate has fallen in recent years for Americans age 19 to 25, however, thanks to a 2010 policy change that allows dependents to remain on their parents’ health insurance plan until their 26th birthday.

Percent uninsured, 2008-2012, based on American Community Survey data.Census Bureau Percent uninsured, 2008-2012, based on American Community Survey data.

There’s huge variation around the country, with the uninsured rate of young adults ranging from about 7.8 percent in Massachusetts and the District of Columbia to 38.7 percent in Texas.

Map reflects uninsured rates for adults age 19 to 34 years old by state.Census Bureau Map reflects uninsured rates for adults age 19 to 34 years old by state.

Of the largest metro areas in the country, the uninsured rate for younger Americans was lowest in Boston-Cambridge-Quincy, Mass., and New Hampshire, at 7.9 percent, and was highest in Miami-Fort Lauderdale-Pompano Beach, Fla., at 41 percent.



The Single-Payer Alternative

Nancy Folbre, professor emerita at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst.

Nancy Folbre is professor emerita of economics at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst.

Rush Limbaugh’s take on the disastrous rollout of the Affordable Care Act could, ironically, warm the hearts of those at the other end of the political spectrum. He contends that President Obama knew all along that the Affordable Care Act would crash and burn, but pushed it through so that the conflagration would clear the way for single-payer health insurance.

The conspiracy charge sounds deranged, but problems with the new health insurance system may indeed revitalize demands for more substantive reforms, which many policy makers and voters set aside in the putative interests of political pragmatism. Whatever the advantages of a single-payer system such as that currently administered by Medicare, one view held, American voters were unlikely to get behind it.

Yet one of the greatest advantages of a single-payer system â€" its relatively low administrative costs â€" have been thrown into sharp relief by problems registering with the new health exchanges. And while Republicans despise the Affordable Care Act despite its conformity with many of their earlier proposals, their proposed changes (other than simple rollback) look complicated, kludgy and costly to administer.

The malfunctioning website has magnified problems inherent in coordinating enrollment across many different companies in many different exchanges in cooperation with many different government agencies. The harmonization challenges are orders of magnitude greater than those faced by a single company or a single state, making streamlining difficult. Improved software can do only so much.

In theory, competition and choice should increase efficiency. In practice, health insurance companies are able to take advantage of the complexity and uncertainty surrounding health care choices to make comparison shopping very difficult.

Lack of clear information about the prices of medical procedures, combined with a proliferation of insurance options whose potential benefits will be strongly affected by unpredictable events (such as being involved in an automobile accident or developing cancer), put consumers in a weak position.

The process of negotiating relationships with new health care providers because old ones are “out of network” is physically and emotionally exhausting. Insurance companies benefit from promoting policies that are difficult to understand and make consumers fearful of any change in their coverage. That fear and aversion has spilled over into the transactions required for many people to benefit from the Affordable Care Act.

David Himmelstein and Steffie Woolhandler, co-founders of Physicians for a National Health Program, regularly assert that elimination of the huge paperwork and overhead imposed by private insurance companies could save enough to cover the estimated 31 million of Americans who will remain uninsured under the Affordable Care Act.

My fellow Economix blogger Uwe E. Reinhardt, expanding on this theme, notes that the Institute of Medicine of the National Academy of Sciences recently estimated excess administrative costs of $191 billion, again more than enough to attain truly universal health care coverage.

Most such estimates are limited to the monetary costs incurred by insurers, doctors and hospitals and don’t include the value of the time that health care consumers must devote to managing a torrent of inscrutable paperwork that can become truly frightening for the critically ill.

Even if its rollout becomes more expeditious, the Affordable Care Act does little to reduce the incentives that companies have to barricade themselves behind high information and transaction costs. In the financial sector, I previously noted, this perverse incentive is described as “strategic price complexity.”

A complicated new program applied to a complicated old industry makes it hard for everyone to figure out exactly what they will be getting relative to what they are paying. As a result, many ordinary people and small businesses fall prey to redistributional paranoia.

Accusations of ripoffs proliferate, along with assertions that the Affordable Care Act is unfair to young people or that it simply represents transfers from the affluent to the poor, or from whites to people of color.

The program clearly has redistributive impact, but much of it will be muted over the life cycle. People who pay more for their insurance will get more benefits in return. The biggest transfers will go from the healthy to the sick (who are sometimes poor precisely because they are sick) and from one part of the health care system (emergency room care) to another (insurance-covered routine care).

But the structure of the program seems unintentionally designed to intensify distributional conflict. Its highly means-tested subsidies create strong political resentments and contribute to very high implicit marginal tax rates on lower-income families.

A single-payer insurance system, whether based on an extension of Medicare or on the Canadian model, promises many profoundly important benefits. Right off the mark, it promises simplicity.

No wonder conservative pundits are afraid of it.



Thursday, November 21, 2013

A Conservative Alternative to Obamacare

DESCRIPTION

Uwe E. Reinhardt is an economics professor at Princeton. He has some financial interests in the health care field.

“Escape From Obamacare” was the headline on The Wall Street Journal’s lead editorial on Nov. 14.

Anticipating, or hoping, that the Affordable Care Act will collapse under the weight of its own architecture and the lack of managerial competence with which it is being put in place, The Journal exhorts Republicans to “revitalize and improve the old individual insurance market” as an alternative to the new system.

For decades that “old individual insurance market” was widely viewed as dysfunctional â€" the source of countless pitiable vignettes in the news media of sky-high premiums quoted to sick applicants, skimpy coverage, denials of coverage and rescissions of policies after insured people fell ill. It is precisely these problems that Title 1 of the new law has sought to address.

So it is fair to ask precisely what improvements in that dysfunctional market The Journal has in mind. As is well known, in health reform the angels and the devils live in the details.

Within the limits of an editorial, The Wall Street Journal could, of course, only hint at what such improvements might be. A somewhat fuller specification was offered in an accompanying op-ed piece, “A Conservative Alternative to Obamacare” by Ramesh Ponnuru and Yuval Levin.

These authors also leave many details of their plan unsaid. But I see in it a close cousin of a much more fully developed plan, published by eight distinguished health economists as a monograph commissioned by the American Enterprise Institute.

Details of that plan are available in the monograph, “Best of Both Worlds: Uniting Universal Coverage and Personal Choice in Health Care,” and in a video of a news briefing on the plan, including critical comments by Nina Owcharenko of the Heritage Foundation and Henry Aaron of the Brookings Institution.

Basically, the authors want to get away from redistributing income from the relatively healthy (regardless of their income) to the relatively sick (regardless of their income) through health insurance premiums, as is the case under the community-rated premiums called for under the Affordable Care Act.

The authors propose instead a plan under which health insurers would be free to base their premiums on the individual applicant’s health status, gender, age and family history, as has been the practice in the old individual market.

Redistribution of income would then take place outside of the pricing of health insurance.

It is impossible to do justice to the plan within the confines of this post, which is why I urge readers to pore over it carefully themselves. But in a nutshell, as I understand it, the plan calls for the following:

1. The current tax preference now accorded employment-based health insurance, under which employer-paid health insurance premiums are a tax-deductible business expense but do not count as taxable compensation of employees, would be abolished and, with it, probably much employment-based coverage.

2. Congress would annually specify a basic package of benefits (the “basic plan”) to be offered by all private health insurers choosing to offer that basic plan and any other, more generous policies they may wish to offer on a new, private national health insurance exchange. The contents of the basic plan could fluctuate over time as Congress addresses the nation’s fiscal situation.

3. All insurers participating in the exchange would have to quote each individual applying for coverage a premium for that basic plan, with the premium based on that applicant’s own medical history and that of the applicant’s family.

4. The federal government would provide the individual applicant support toward the premium for the basic plan if that premium exceeded a certain percentage of the applicant’s adjusted gross income.

5. These federal premium support payments would be determined for each individual applicant on the basis of the lowest or second-lowest premium that individual was quoted for the basic plan.

6. Individuals would be free to purchase more generous coverage than the basic plan, at premiums also based on their own and their families’ medical histories.

7. The federal-state Medicaid program would be abolished. Medicaid beneficiaries would be channeled to the new, private national exchange on which they would receive, at no cost to them, coverage for the basic benefit package. That coverage probably would be much leaner than Medicaid’s current fairly comprehensive benefit package.

8. All Americans would pay a small safety-net tax to cover emergency care for individuals who are uninsured at the time of their emergency.

9. Funds now spent on Medicaid ($332 billion in 2011) and tax revenue gained by abolishing the current tax preference for employment-based insurance (about $300 billion a year) would be used to finance the federal premium-support payments.

The authors emphasize that theirs is only a broad sketch of the concept, leaving much flexibility for specifics.

To illustrate their concept, the authors develop a version under which the deductible for the basic plan rises with household income and according to whether the household is “extremely burdened” with health spending. An “extremely burdened” household would be one with income below 600 percent of the federal poverty level and whose medical expenditures in a year are greater than spending by 80 percent of all households in America. Table 3 of the monograph shows these deductibles and other co-payments.

To illustrate, for a family of four with an income of 150 percent of the federal poverty level ($33,525) and “not extremely burdened,” the deductible would be 15 percent of household income ($5,029). The family would also face a 10 percent coinsurance rate on all medical bills. If that household were deemed “extremely burdened,” the deductible would be zero, but the coinsurance rate would still be 10 percent.

By contrast, for a family of four with a household income of 700 percent of the federal poverty level ($156,450), the deductible would be 70 percent of income ($109,515) and the coinsurance rate 20 percent, whether or not the family were “extremely burdened” by medical bills.

At a household income of $223,500 and above, the deductible for this family would be equal to household income and the coinsurance rate would be 20 percent.

Families with high deductibles on the basic plan could, of course, purchase coverage with much lower deductibles, at premiums pegged to their health status and family medical history. Presumably, insurers could deny applicants such coverage, as they can now. Furthermore, it appears that insurers could also rescind policies in force if the applicant had submitted inaccurate health-status data as traditionally they have been able to do.

I salute the eight economists for sketching out for us a plan that seeks to combine premiums pegged on the health status of individuals with income redistribution outside of premium-setting.

The political appeal of such a complicated plan is for each reader to determine.

I also leave it to the reader to imagine the architecture of the new, private national health insurance exchange required by this scheme. It would be even more challenging than is Healthcare.gov under Obamacare.

Like Healthcare.gov, the new private insurance exchange would have to link to the Internal Revenue Service to verify income and to perform the complex calculations for premium support, if any.

That exchange would have to feature a plethora of premium quotes for the basic plan and for all more generous plans likely to be offered on the exchange, which might run into the hundreds.

Finally, to facilitate risk-based, individualized premium setting, that exchange would have to elicit from every applicant information in great detail on the applicant’s medical history and that of his or her family. That intimate information would then be broadcast by the exchange to all private health insurers competing on the exchange.

Is this what a “new, improved old individual health insurance market” might look like?



An Optimistic View of the United States

Phillip Swagel is a professor at the School of Public Policy at the University of Maryland and was assistant secretary for economic policy at the Treasury Department from 2006 to 2009.

In the face of the political impasse that thwarts progress on so many economic issues facing the United States â€" spending changes, tax reform, immigration, and so on â€" it’s enlightening to get a new perspective from stepping outside the country. I’ve been doing just that this week, as part of a group of economists considering fiscal policy issues at a conference in Abu Dhabi put on by the World Economic Forum.  The conference, labeled the Summit on the Global Agenda, is a sort of minor league for the big show held each year in Davos, Switzerland. It’s the wonk version of double-A ball.

To my surprise, I’ve come away more optimistic about the United States economy. It’s not that we’ve solved our fiscal problems or avoided the next shutdown or debt ceiling debacle. Nor is the United States evidently any closer to a bipartisan agreement on policies to bolster near-term growth or resolve our long-term fiscal challenge. Not by a long shot, as was captured in an insightful article this week by Jackie Calmes of The New York Times.

But my policy working group includes a sizable contingent of Europeans, and listening to their discussion of economic policy making in the euro zone makes clear just how much progress the United States has made since the financial crisis flared in the summer of 2007. Europe is still dealing with the unresolved issues of the crisis, including the debts of governments and households that hold back spending, and the overhang of bad loans at banks that deter the lending needed to support new investment and job creation.  On each of these dimensions and more, the United States has taken at least some positive steps while continental Europe has virtually wasted six years.

The International Monetary Fund’s latest forecast is for 1 percent growth in gross domestic product in the euro area in 2014 â€" an improvement after two years of recession, but dismal compared with the 2.6 percent growth expected in the United States. (Paul Krugman puts it more sharply â€" that the euro recovery is worse even than that of the 1930s.) And this slim euro-area expansion masks wide disparities in the situation across countries. In Germany, the unemployment rate has remained around 5.5 percent, better than in the United States, while crisis-ridden countries like Greece, Italy, and Spain face much worse â€" 27 percent unemployment this year in Greece and Spain, and 12 percent in Italy.

The usual adjustment mechanism for a country in such straits would be to achieve export-led growth through expansionary monetary policy and a weaker currency. But countries in the euro area do not control their own monetary policy. That is up to the European Central Bank, which so far has not followed the Federal Reserve in aggressive monetary easing.  Leaving the euro is off the table for political reasons. The E.C.B. recently made a small cut in the policy interest rate and has purchased government bonds to help the weak countries, but these actions so far have been just enough to avoid catastrophe like a default in Italy or Spain that inflicts widespread losses on European banks. One might see the E.C.B.’s reluctance to do more to stimulate the euro area economy as a means to keep the pressure on for fiscal adjustment â€" to ensure that the formerly profligate governments achieve rectitude.

Meanwhile, European policy makers debate how much cash can be sent south to ease the pain of the adjustment while avoiding such generosity that governments deviate from fiscal austerity.  It would not be a surprise if other countries in Europe eventually are forced to take on some of the debt burdens so that the weak countries can finally grow again. But the policy debate is far from this, leaving austerity to grind down wages and incomes so that companies in the south of Europe can compete with the German export juggernaut.

European financial markets are more bank-centric than those in the United States, where bonds and securitized assets reign, amplifying the negative impact of having euro area banks weighted down by bad loans. Yet another stress test is planned in 2014 to identify the bad banks and either strengthen or weed them out, but previous such exercises in Europe did not restart lending.  And policy makers are still struggling to develop mechanisms to shut down bad banks in a consistent way across the euro area â€" something that is routine across the 50 states here. Ultimately, a new round of bank bailouts is likely to be needed in Europe, but this requires yet more cash to flow from the strong economies to the weak ones, and the political decision for this again is far from being made.  Just imagine the problem if it had taken five years instead of five weeks to pass the legislation that ceated TARP to stabilize the United States financial system. That is Europe.

Ultimately, achieving the stronger growth that will help European countries get out from the weight of their debts probably requires structural reforms to increase the flexibility of European labor markets. This is yet another longstanding debate in Europe, and probably means changing aspects of the cherished welfare state - another political nonstarter. In the meantime, Europe is a slow-motion train wreck, unable to switch onto a better track.

The contrast with the United States is vast, starting with the concerted efforts to stanch the financial crisis that were started in one administration and then carried on by another.

With fiscal policy, the United States came close to a debt default not too many weeks ago, but we have actually made some progress on fiscal consolidation, and more is likely in 2014 through the combined impact of the sequester that limits spending and rising revenues from stronger growth.  The latest fiscal update from the Congressional Budget Office has the budget deficit down to 2 percent of G.D.P. in 2015 and the debt level falling slightly to 68 percent of G.D.P. in 2018. The long-term fiscal challenge remains: deficits and debt levels are set to soar over the ensuing decades and acting sooner will make the resulting adjustments less difficult. But there appears little prospect of a funding problem for several years at least, meaning that we can have measures to take hold over time rather than being forced into a sharp austerity.

The United States further has made considerable progress on financial policy dimensions that stymie Europe, with household and business debt burdens down (though student loan debt is a rising concern), and banks are much stronger with greater capital ratios and fewer bad loans than in 2008.  Financial regulatory reform has provided United States policy makers with important new tools, albeit as yet untested, to deal with future problems including at large banks.

To be sure, the unemployment rate is still too high and job creation not yet robust.  But the aspect of the American economic situation that makes me most optimistic compared to Europe is that we are not just growing, but have the potential to do even better. Immigration reform, while politically difficult, is manifestly in our economic interest and would foster growth. The same is true for policies that expand trade, such as completion of the Trans-Pacific Partnership.  And the innovative sectors of the economy, if anything, appear to be accelerating in the pace of their entrepreneurial fervent.

Having taken steps to move beyond the financial crisis, the United States is thus in a favorable position, with an opportunity to take on longer-term economic challenges such as immigration, education, inequality, retirement security and the necessary fiscal adjustment over time, including reforms of entitlement programs. This last point is vital and should not be delayed simply because the fiscal situation is stable for a period. Indeed, a key point my group made to others at the Abu Dhabi conference was that fiscal sustainability is essential to ensure that resources are available for the public sector to contribute to addressing all other agenda items.

In a sense, a key challenge for countries of the euro zone is to finally take steps to resolve their fiscal and financial problems, at least enough so that policy makers can lift their horizons to address longer-term concerns. Seen from the outside perspective, it looks as if the United States has that opportunity.



An Optimistic View of the United States

Phillip Swagel is a professor at the School of Public Policy at the University of Maryland and was assistant secretary for economic policy at the Treasury Department from 2006 to 2009.

In the face of the political impasse that thwarts progress on so many economic issues facing the United States â€" spending changes, tax reform, immigration, and so on â€" it’s enlightening to get a new perspective from stepping outside the country. I’ve been doing just that this week, as part of a group of economists considering fiscal policy issues at a conference in Abu Dhabi put on by the World Economic Forum.  The conference, labeled the Summit on the Global Agenda, is a sort of minor league for the big show held each year in Davos, Switzerland. It’s the wonk version of double-A ball.

To my surprise, I’ve come away more optimistic about the United States economy. It’s not that we’ve solved our fiscal problems or avoided the next shutdown or debt ceiling debacle. Nor is the United States evidently any closer to a bipartisan agreement on policies to bolster near-term growth or resolve our long-term fiscal challenge. Not by a long shot, as was captured in an insightful article this week by Jackie Calmes of The New York Times.

But my policy working group includes a sizable contingent of Europeans, and listening to their discussion of economic policy making in the euro zone makes clear just how much progress the United States has made since the financial crisis flared in the summer of 2007. Europe is still dealing with the unresolved issues of the crisis, including the debts of governments and households that hold back spending, and the overhang of bad loans at banks that deter the lending needed to support new investment and job creation.  On each of these dimensions and more, the United States has taken at least some positive steps while continental Europe has virtually wasted six years.

The International Monetary Fund’s latest forecast is for 1 percent growth in gross domestic product in the euro area in 2014 â€" an improvement after two years of recession, but dismal compared with the 2.6 percent growth expected in the United States. (Paul Krugman puts it more sharply â€" that the euro recovery is worse even than that of the 1930s.) And this slim euro-area expansion masks wide disparities in the situation across countries. In Germany, the unemployment rate has remained around 5.5 percent, better than in the United States, while crisis-ridden countries like Greece, Italy, and Spain face much worse â€" 27 percent unemployment this year in Greece and Spain, and 12 percent in Italy.

The usual adjustment mechanism for a country in such straits would be to achieve export-led growth through expansionary monetary policy and a weaker currency. But countries in the euro area do not control their own monetary policy. That is up to the European Central Bank, which so far has not followed the Federal Reserve in aggressive monetary easing.  Leaving the euro is off the table for political reasons. The E.C.B. recently made a small cut in the policy interest rate and has purchased government bonds to help the weak countries, but these actions so far have been just enough to avoid catastrophe like a default in Italy or Spain that inflicts widespread losses on European banks. One might see the E.C.B.’s reluctance to do more to stimulate the euro area economy as a means to keep the pressure on for fiscal adjustment â€" to ensure that the formerly profligate governments achieve rectitude.

Meanwhile, European policy makers debate how much cash can be sent south to ease the pain of the adjustment while avoiding such generosity that governments deviate from fiscal austerity.  It would not be a surprise if other countries in Europe eventually are forced to take on some of the debt burdens so that the weak countries can finally grow again. But the policy debate is far from this, leaving austerity to grind down wages and incomes so that companies in the south of Europe can compete with the German export juggernaut.

European financial markets are more bank-centric than those in the United States, where bonds and securitized assets reign, amplifying the negative impact of having euro area banks weighted down by bad loans. Yet another stress test is planned in 2014 to identify the bad banks and either strengthen or weed them out, but previous such exercises in Europe did not restart lending.  And policy makers are still struggling to develop mechanisms to shut down bad banks in a consistent way across the euro area â€" something that is routine across the 50 states here. Ultimately, a new round of bank bailouts is likely to be needed in Europe, but this requires yet more cash to flow from the strong economies to the weak ones, and the political decision for this again is far from being made.  Just imagine the problem if it had taken five years instead of five weeks to pass the legislation that ceated TARP to stabilize the United States financial system. That is Europe.

Ultimately, achieving the stronger growth that will help European countries get out from the weight of their debts probably requires structural reforms to increase the flexibility of European labor markets. This is yet another longstanding debate in Europe, and probably means changing aspects of the cherished welfare state - another political nonstarter. In the meantime, Europe is a slow-motion train wreck, unable to switch onto a better track.

The contrast with the United States is vast, starting with the concerted efforts to stanch the financial crisis that were started in one administration and then carried on by another.

With fiscal policy, the United States came close to a debt default not too many weeks ago, but we have actually made some progress on fiscal consolidation, and more is likely in 2014 through the combined impact of the sequester that limits spending and rising revenues from stronger growth.  The latest fiscal update from the Congressional Budget Office has the budget deficit down to 2 percent of G.D.P. in 2015 and the debt level falling slightly to 68 percent of G.D.P. in 2018. The long-term fiscal challenge remains: deficits and debt levels are set to soar over the ensuing decades and acting sooner will make the resulting adjustments less difficult. But there appears little prospect of a funding problem for several years at least, meaning that we can have measures to take hold over time rather than being forced into a sharp austerity.

The United States further has made considerable progress on financial policy dimensions that stymie Europe, with household and business debt burdens down (though student loan debt is a rising concern), and banks are much stronger with greater capital ratios and fewer bad loans than in 2008.  Financial regulatory reform has provided United States policy makers with important new tools, albeit as yet untested, to deal with future problems including at large banks.

To be sure, the unemployment rate is still too high and job creation not yet robust.  But the aspect of the American economic situation that makes me most optimistic compared to Europe is that we are not just growing, but have the potential to do even better. Immigration reform, while politically difficult, is manifestly in our economic interest and would foster growth. The same is true for policies that expand trade, such as completion of the Trans-Pacific Partnership.  And the innovative sectors of the economy, if anything, appear to be accelerating in the pace of their entrepreneurial fervent.

Having taken steps to move beyond the financial crisis, the United States is thus in a favorable position, with an opportunity to take on longer-term economic challenges such as immigration, education, inequality, retirement security and the necessary fiscal adjustment over time, including reforms of entitlement programs. This last point is vital and should not be delayed simply because the fiscal situation is stable for a period. Indeed, a key point my group made to others at the Abu Dhabi conference was that fiscal sustainability is essential to ensure that resources are available for the public sector to contribute to addressing all other agenda items.

In a sense, a key challenge for countries of the euro zone is to finally take steps to resolve their fiscal and financial problems, at least enough so that policy makers can lift their horizons to address longer-term concerns. Seen from the outside perspective, it looks as if the United States has that opportunity.



Readers React to Unemployment’s Revolving Door

When you lose your job, suddenly nothing feels secure. That was one of the most common themes among more than 700 comments on Annie Lowrey’s article “Caught in a Revolving Door of Unemployment” last weekend. Jenner Barrington-Ward, the subject of the article, found herself homeless after decades of employment. Two readers shared their own stories of homelessness.

“My whole life is in storage, and I fear letting go of all of it will strip me of a good part of my identity,” Debbie in New York wrote.

“After 35 years-plus of management/corporate positions, I find myself in retail working with 20-somethings,” she said, adding that she earns ” 65 to 75 percent less than what I formerly earned.” After moving four times in two years and declaring bankruptcy, “I don’t know who I am anymore,” she added. “All my friends are married and settled, and this feels like a nightmare from which I cannot wake up.”

Sarah in Connecticut replied: “I see nothing changing. Wearing concrete shoes. … Yup, my life is in storage, too.”

Few readers, many approaching retirement age, expressed confidence in their own job security. The comments are full of sympathy for the unemployed, along with pleas for additional support.

“Someone needs to step up and offer her security for at least six months, not the impersonal state or government, some person!” David S. wrote. “I have been paying for a friend’s phone just so he could have a stable telephone while he looks for a job. I have bought monthly MetroCards for him so he did not have to walk to job interviews. It’s not just me doing for him â€" it’s a group of us.”

Many of the unemployed wrote that the support of loved ones kept them going. “If it weren’t for my husband, I would be in exactly the same boat,” Beth Rogers of Bethesda, Md., wrote. “Just praying that he doesn’t fire me.”

Other ways readers said they were surviving included odd jobs, borrowing money and going back to school at 60. A few evangelized about entrepreneurship, but others warned it’s not always a cure-all: Jen D. in New Jersey said her brother “was laid off early on in the Great Recession and thought his I.T. skills would be valued by employers,” adding: “All employers saw was an older guy who had been out of work a while. When he died, he had an old car to his name and over $30,000 in debt that he had no way to pay. He had even tried to start a business, but with no marketing background, it failed miserably.”

Not everyone feels hopeless. Margary Fieldman in Boston said she was laid off from an administrative position at the same employer as Ms. Barrington-Ward in 2011 and was given eight weeks’ notice and help finding another position elsewhere â€" and there were plenty of options.

Another reader complained of problems filling positions for warehouse workers, and invited anyone to apply: “Almost anyone can do this job, there is no lifting involved. … A large portion of the new hires quit after the third day, once they realize what the job is.”

Some readers threw their hats in, but most were skeptical of $13.50 as a living wage, or that older, less mobile individuals could do the work. Another reader questioned whether she or Ms. Barrington-Ward would be eligible: “Because I know people who have had this woman’s experience, including myself, I also know that those types of warehouse jobs, in Massachusetts, tend NOT to hire black people, or anyone with a college degree.”

Many readers cited age, and the higher salary requirements and insurance costs that often come with it, as a particular barrier in finding work. A common enemy in the comments was incompetent human resources departments, and some readers suggested using social networks to circumvent them.

A few comments asked what legitimate reason an employer could have for turning down an applicant for being unemployed. But one reader had a couple of ideas:

“The last person any employer wants on their payroll is someone … who might be collecting unemployment benefits for a significant period of time at some future date,” wrote Mike Schumann of St. Paul. “When a person has been collecting unemployment for an extended period, it sends a message to potential employers that the person is not aggressive and hustling to resolve their personal situation.”

The consequences of unemployment can be far-reaching. And this recession has seen a higher-than-usual increase in suicides. Many commenters reported that they had lost or feared losing loved ones. Others face their own struggle with depression.

After ending a 20-year marriage, Sarah in Connecticut said she was “now staying in a friend’s place, but that can’t go on forever.”

“I am so far in debt, part of me wants to cash out my Roth and pay off the debt, then end it all,” she wrote. “I see no other alternative. I used to be a positive person with an incredibly optimistic attitude but that ship has sailed. That’s the most depressing part of all this â€" it just continues to get worse every single passing day. When you lose hope … what more is there?”



Readers React to Unemployment’s Revolving Door

When you lose your job, suddenly nothing feels secure. That was one of the most common themes among more than 700 comments on Annie Lowrey’s article “Caught in a Revolving Door of Unemployment” last weekend. Jenner Barrington-Ward, the subject of the article, found herself homeless after decades of employment. Two readers shared their own stories of homelessness.

“My whole life is in storage, and I fear letting go of all of it will strip me of a good part of my identity,” Debbie in New York wrote.

“After 35 years-plus of management/corporate positions, I find myself in retail working with 20-somethings,” she said, adding that she earns ” 65 to 75 percent less than what I formerly earned.” After moving four times in two years and declaring bankruptcy, “I don’t know who I am anymore,” she added. “All my friends are married and settled, and this feels like a nightmare from which I cannot wake up.”

Sarah in Connecticut replied: “I see nothing changing. Wearing concrete shoes. … Yup, my life is in storage, too.”

Few readers, many approaching retirement age, expressed confidence in their own job security. The comments are full of sympathy for the unemployed, along with pleas for additional support.

“Someone needs to step up and offer her security for at least six months, not the impersonal state or government, some person!” David S. wrote. “I have been paying for a friend’s phone just so he could have a stable telephone while he looks for a job. I have bought monthly MetroCards for him so he did not have to walk to job interviews. It’s not just me doing for him â€" it’s a group of us.”

Many of the unemployed wrote that the support of loved ones kept them going. “If it weren’t for my husband, I would be in exactly the same boat,” Beth Rogers of Bethesda, Md., wrote. “Just praying that he doesn’t fire me.”

Other ways readers said they were surviving included odd jobs, borrowing money and going back to school at 60. A few evangelized about entrepreneurship, but others warned it’s not always a cure-all: Jen D. in New Jersey said her brother “was laid off early on in the Great Recession and thought his I.T. skills would be valued by employers,” adding: “All employers saw was an older guy who had been out of work a while. When he died, he had an old car to his name and over $30,000 in debt that he had no way to pay. He had even tried to start a business, but with no marketing background, it failed miserably.”

Not everyone feels hopeless. Margary Fieldman in Boston said she was laid off from an administrative position at the same employer as Ms. Barrington-Ward in 2011 and was given eight weeks’ notice and help finding another position elsewhere â€" and there were plenty of options.

Another reader complained of problems filling positions for warehouse workers, and invited anyone to apply: “Almost anyone can do this job, there is no lifting involved. … A large portion of the new hires quit after the third day, once they realize what the job is.”

Some readers threw their hats in, but most were skeptical of $13.50 as a living wage, or that older, less mobile individuals could do the work. Another reader questioned whether she or Ms. Barrington-Ward would be eligible: “Because I know people who have had this woman’s experience, including myself, I also know that those types of warehouse jobs, in Massachusetts, tend NOT to hire black people, or anyone with a college degree.”

Many readers cited age, and the higher salary requirements and insurance costs that often come with it, as a particular barrier in finding work. A common enemy in the comments was incompetent human resources departments, and some readers suggested using social networks to circumvent them.

A few comments asked what legitimate reason an employer could have for turning down an applicant for being unemployed. But one reader had a couple of ideas:

“The last person any employer wants on their payroll is someone … who might be collecting unemployment benefits for a significant period of time at some future date,” wrote Mike Schumann of St. Paul. “When a person has been collecting unemployment for an extended period, it sends a message to potential employers that the person is not aggressive and hustling to resolve their personal situation.”

The consequences of unemployment can be far-reaching. And this recession has seen a higher-than-usual increase in suicides. Many commenters reported that they had lost or feared losing loved ones. Others face their own struggle with depression.

After ending a 20-year marriage, Sarah in Connecticut said she was “now staying in a friend’s place, but that can’t go on forever.”

“I am so far in debt, part of me wants to cash out my Roth and pay off the debt, then end it all,” she wrote. “I see no other alternative. I used to be a positive person with an incredibly optimistic attitude but that ship has sailed. That’s the most depressing part of all this â€" it just continues to get worse every single passing day. When you lose hope … what more is there?”



Wednesday, November 20, 2013

Limiting the Fed

DESCRIPTION

Simon Johnson, former chief economist of the International Monetary Fund, is the Ronald A. Kurtz Professor of Entrepreneurship at the M.I.T. Sloan School of Management and co-author of “White House Burning: The Founding Fathers, Our National Debt, and Why It Matters to You.”

In a provocative speech this week, Charles I. Plosser, the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, proposed a new approach for the Federal Reserve System. The Fed, he said, should focus only on controlling inflation, strictly limit the assets it buys, follow a more rules-based approach to setting interest rates and place binding constraints on its emergency lending activities.

Of course, this is not so much a new set of ideas as an attempt to return to a much more traditional perspective on how the Fed should operate - not back to the pre-1930s gold standard, but perhaps back to the early days of Fed independence in the 1950s.

Mr. Plosser is concerned about the recent expansion of the central banking mandate and activities. He is right to want to shift norms around what the Fed does, but unfortunately his proposals in this speech underplay the Fed’s responsibility for the nation’s recent economic crisis, as well as what has happened to the financial system in recent decades.

Getting the Fed off the hook for regulating the system could make sense, but only if there was much more structural change in and around banking than Congress has mandated or that the Fed seems willing to push for.

Mr. Plosser’s concerns are expressed in eloquent and plain terms. He was speaking at a recent Cato Institute conference, “Was the Fed a Good Idea?”; some attendees apparently had a more negative view of the Fed. In fact, some participants seriously propose to end the Fed as we know it.

Mr. Plosser’s approach is more measured. He fully understands and emphasizes that the Fed has made important contributions over the last 100 years.

He is also not overly focused on the literal meaning of “price stability.” One awkward truth for most modern central bankers is that they say they want stable prices, but what they really mean is inflation at or around 2 percent a year.

This is enormously annoying to traditionalists who hark back to the gold era of the late 19th and early 20th centuries, when prices sometimes went up and sometimes went down. Now prices and wages only go up; the question is each year is just by how much.

Allowing prices to rise steadily is a deliberate policy, intended to avoid the deflation (i.e., falling prices) experienced during the Great Depression. When you borrow in dollars and prices fall, you end up owing more in real terms - with the likely consequence that you will soon be unable to afford the payments.

Mr. Plosser’s main point is fair: the Fed may in recent decades have taken on too much responsibility for reducing short-term fluctuations in employment. The famous “Greenspan put” was all about limiting the downside in financial markets and also in the real economy.

But at the same time, Fed policy contributed to the buildup of risks in the financial sector before September 2008.

In recent discussions of former Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner’s career, for example, much has been made of the fact that the government recovered the value of its investments in financial-sector companies.

This is true, but we should not overlook the fact that - as president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York from 2003 to early 2009 - Mr. Geithner was in charge of the analytical and policy team that should have seen trouble brewing but that remained remarkably complacent. The cost to the economy and to millions of people - jobs lost, mortgages foreclosed and persistent unemployment - is huge.

I am sympathetic to Mr. Plosser’s core point: the Fed has taken on too much, with the result that it creates moral hazard in the financial system.

But remember that Lehman Brothers was not saved in September 2008; it was allowed to go bankrupt, with devastating consequences to the world’s financial system (again, not anticipated by the Fed).

Just saying with regard to big banks, “let them fail,” is not satisfactory when this can cause a global financial meltdown. We no longer have the financial system of the 1950s.

Mr. Plosser would be on stronger ground if he were to support structural changes in the financial system, such as making the largest banks smaller, so that any one of them could fail without causing a worldwide recession. (To be fair, Mr. Plosser has tackled the issue of too big to fail more directly in other speeches. Again, I find much to agree with in his analysis, but to my mind he does not pursue his own reasoning to its full logical conclusion.)

Mr. Plosser is right to want to scale back the role of the Fed. Unfortunately, unless he also scales back the largest banks and the risks that they and other parts of the financial system can pose, his suggested solution would become a noncredible commitment.

If American regulations are minimal - or not enforced by the Fed - and a global megabank actually fails (think of Goldman Sachs or JPMorgan Chase), the choice again before officials would be unsavory bailout or another Great Depression.

Which would the Fed choose? It would always choose the bailout, putting us right back where we have been for the last five years: ex post downside insurance to key parts of the financial system provided for free by the official sector.

That kind of favoritism in credit policy - helping some companies and some sectors over others - is exactly the kind of arrangement that Mr. Plosser criticizes so effectively. To limit the Fed, we need to limit the concentration of risks in the financial system.