Total Pageviews

Tuesday, April 22, 2014

Economix Meets the Gales of Change

Creative destruction, an economic theory credited to Joseph Schumpeter, posits that institutions are destroyed so that new institutions can grow and flourish.

This blog, Economix, is perhaps another example of Schumpeter’s gale. Its five-and-a-half-year run as the location for insights into everything economic has come to an end. But in its place will rise a new site, The Upshot, which will be a plain-spoken guide to politics, policy and, importantly, economics. The brainchild of David Leonhardt, one of the founders of Economix, it will carry on the best practices of Economix: “illuminate and distill a discussion, rather than muddy it.”

That is how Economix described its mission in its inaugural post in September 2008 in the depths of the Great Recession. The blog took the talents of the economic reporters of The New York Times and added prominent economists to the mix.

The Upshot will remain a prominent platform for writing on the science of everyday life. We have hired Neil Irwin, a Washington Post economics writer and author of “The Alchemists: Three Central Bankers and a World on Fire,” and Josh Barro, an MSNBC commentator and a former writer for Business Insider and Bloomberg View. Claire Cain Miller, formerly a Times technology reporter, will be a full-time presence. Annie Lowrey, Binyamin Appelbaum, Nelson Schwartz, Eduardo Porter, Shaila Dewan and Floyd Norris, The Times’s economic team, will frequently add their thoughts. Several regular contributors to Economix will continue: Jared Bernstein, Phillip Swagel and Uwe Reinhardt, who was with Economix from the beginning.

The Upshot will also feature the thoughts of several more provocative economists, including Sendhil Mullainathan, a Harvard economics professor, and Justin Wolfers, professor of economics and public policy at the University of Michigan.

Aaron Carroll and Austin Frakt â€" who write about health policy on the Incidental Economist blog â€" have also joined The Upshot. Dr. Carroll is a professor of pediatrics at the Indiana University School of Medicine whose research bridges information technology, medical decision making, medical ethics and health policy. Mr. Frakt is an economist with appointments at VA Boston Healthcare System, Boston University and the Leonard Davis Institute of the University of Pennsylvania.

It’s quite a team.

Thank you for reading Economix through the years, and for your comments and arguments. (Rest assured, everything will remained archived on the Times site.) And please follow us at The Upshot.



Friday, April 18, 2014

Mortgage Reform Is Worth the Small Extra Cost to Borrowers

Phillip Swagel is a professor at the School of Public Policy at the University of Maryland and was assistant secretary for economic policy at the Treasury Department from 2006 to 2009.

In the current housing financing system, shareholders and management of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac got the considerable profits in good times, and when the housing market collapsed, taxpayers were stuck with the bill â€" a $190 billion tab in the recent crisis.

A Senate proposal for a new system would have private investors rather than taxpayers take on most of the risks and returns involved with mortgage lending â€" if a misguided obsession with the small additional cost to borrowers doesn’t sink the reforms.

The proposal put forward recently by Senators Tim Johnson, Democrat from South Dakota, and Michael Crapo, Republican from Idaho, who lead the Senate banking committee, would bring about a housing finance system driven first and foremost by market incentives rather than by government dictates.  There are many pieces to the proposal, including support for affordable housing and an innovative approach by which to reward financial firms that serve a broad range of customers and penalize those that do not.

But reducing the government involvement in housing finance and bringing back private capital is at the heart of the bill, which would end the anomalous situation in which the housing finance giants Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are private companies that earn enormous profits but remain under the control of a government regulator.

Building on an earlier effort by Senators Bob Corker, Republican from Tennessee, and Mark R. Warner,  Democrat from Virginia, the Crapo-Johnson legislation reduces taxpayer exposure to housing risk by requiring private investors to risk their own capital in an amount equal to 10 percent of the value of the mortgages receiving a government guarantee. The government would then sell secondary insurance on mortgage-backed securities composed of qualifying home loans (with underwriting protections written into the legislation). As mortgages go bad (which they do even in good times), the private capital would take the first losses and provide a buffer against the need for the government to put out cash on its guarantee.

The 10 percent capital requirement is large enough to protect taxpayers. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac together in the crisis suffered losses of about 4 percent of the value of their assets, meaning it would take an economic upheaval considerably worse than that of the last seven years to burn through the private capital protecting taxpayers. In exchange for the increased role of the private sector, the existence of the secondary government backstop would ensure that mortgages remained available to Americans across financial market ups and downs.

Adding this protection for taxpayers has a cost, since private investors require compensation to take on housing risk. This translates into higher mortgage interest rates for borrowers.

Before the financial crisis, advocates for reforms were sometimes attacked as “antihousing,” on the grounds that the higher interest rates from reduced government support would make it more difficult for Americans to become homeowners. This complaint is misguided, since the impact on interest rates from the Crapo-Johnson is the consequence of fixing the flaw in the old system that left taxpayers at risk: the higher cost for borrowers corresponds to the protection for taxpayers that was missing.

Moreover, Senators Crapo and Johnson address concerns over the impact of higher interest rates on low- and moderate-income families by including billions of dollars to subsidize affordable housing, both rental and owner-occupied.

Mortgage bankers argue alongside housing advocates for a private capital requirement of only 5 percent rather than 10. There is an irony in the apparent alliance, since groups that support affordable housing subsidies typically look skeptically at the role of large banks in the economy. Many left-leaning groups supported a past legislative proposal to impose a 15 percent capital requirement on megabanks, with the aim of protecting taxpayers against bailing out institutions that are too big to fail. Presumably their view is that the higher capital requirement would have only a modest negative impact on bank lending â€" the opposite of the argument that 10 percent capital would have a large impact on housing-related activity.

It would be hard to know the overall result for home buyers until the new system was in place, but the incremental impact on interest rates of having 10 percent private capital to protect taxpayers rather than 5 percent is likely to be modest. The first 5 percent of private capital slated to take losses would  be costly, because investors know their money is on the line in the event of another housing debacle. But this 5 percent private capital would be present under all legislative proposals.

The cost of the next 5 percent of private capital to take losses ahead of taxpayers is at issue. It takes only a moment’s reflection to recognize that the cost is likely to be modest once a new system with more capital is put into place over time.  The reasoning is that the sixth to tenth percentage points of private capital would be at risk only after the first 5 percent was wiped out. Or as I put it in testimony in October before the Senate Banking Committee, if 5 percent private capital is enough to protect taxpayers, then the next 5 percent private capital is safe and cannot be expensive. If the additional private capital is expensive, then it must be that 5 percent is not enough to protect taxpayers â€" it cannot be both ways.

The best estimates to date suggest that mortgage interest rates under the Crapo-Johnson proposal would rise less than half a percentage point compared to the current system.  By way of comparison, interest rates are likely to increase by multiple percentage points in the next two or three years as the Federal Reserve moves away from the zero interest rates in place since late 2008.  Just as Janet L. Yellen, the Fed chief, will be doing her job to return interest rates back to normal, so, too, will Congress by protecting taxpayers against another housing bailout.

One reasonable hesitation for undertaking any housing finance reform is that it would rearrange a sector of the economy central to the economic and social aspirations of American families. We have all seen the confusion created by the Affordable Care Act in forcing too many people to endure undesired changes in their insurance policies and choice of physicians, and setting the stage for galloping insurance premium increases in the future.

But the Crapo-Johnson bill is the opposite of Obamacare. It brings the private sector back into a housing finance system now dominated by the government. Market incentives rather than government officials would determine the availability of mortgage financing, allowing private investors to extend mortgage loans to potential home buyers who today are prevented from buying a home by the pendulum swing to overly strict post-crisis lending standards.  Indeed, bringing in considerable private capital will not just protect taxpayers, but also provide an incentive for prudence in lending on the part of investors whose money is at risk.

Without housing finance reform, the government will continue to dominate mortgage markets. The alternative to the Crapo-Johnson bill is not a fully private system but instead setting in concrete the current situation and thus effectively nationalizing the housing finance system.  A fully private mortgage market might seem attractive on paper, but it ignores the political and financial reality that any future Congress and President will act to stabilize mortgage markets if Americans cannot obtain home loans.

The government guarantee in housing is thus latent, even in a system that is ostensibly private. Pretending otherwise would inadvertently recreate a salient defect of the past: the implicit backstop under which shareholders and the management of Fannie and Freddie kept the upside in good times and taxpayers were stuck with the bill when the housing market collapsed â€" a $190 billion tab in the recent crisis. Rather than creating a system that is private only until the inevitable next crisis, it is thus preferable to make clear the government’s limited role and to ensure that an immense amount of private capital takes losses before another taxpayer bailout. Formalizing a taxpayer backstop on housing is anathema on the right, but it is the first and necessary step to shrinking the government’s role.

Democrats might hesitate at reducing the government role but applaud the innovative approach in the legislation under which mortgage companies have a financial incentive to serve all borrowers capable of sustaining a mortgage (and not just high-income families). This would be in addition to money for affordable housing activities through mechanisms created in the Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008 but that did not receive funds as a result of the financial difficulties at Fannie and Freddie.

A sticking point from the left is that many housing advocates expect Melvin L. Watt, the director of the Federal Housing Finance Agency, to put the money into affordable housing activities out of the now-considerable profits of Fannie and Freddie. Mr. Watt has the legal authority to do this now â€"  some would say that the 2008 law requires him to do so.  If the money for affordable housing flows ahead of broader reform, however, an important incentive for left-leaning stakeholders to support Crapo-Johnson would be removed.  It is ironic that action by Mr. Watt could actually undermine a measure supported by President Obama.

Reform of housing finance remains among the chief unaddressed legacies of the financial crisis. The Crapo-Johnson bill is truly a bipartisan compromise, satisfying neither side in whole but constituting a vast improvement over the current housing finance system in which taxpayers are at risk even while too many families cannot obtain mortgages.

 



Thursday, April 17, 2014

In Europe, Auto Sales Are Still Low, But They Are Rising

European auto sales figures for March, reported today, show that slightly more new cars were sold in the euro zone during the most recent 12 months than had been sold a year earlier. The increase was a tiny one, just 0.4 percent.

Source: European Automobile Manufacturers Association

Monthly figures have been rising for some time, but this was the first year-over-year rise since early 2010, and another sign that economic growth is returning to Europe.

Some of the largest gains were in countries that have experienced severe recessions. Sales in Greece, Portugal, Spain and Ireland were all at least 10 percent higher than they had been during the previous 12 months.

Source: European Automobile Manufacturers Association

To some extent, however, that merely reflects how low sales had fallen. Even with the the gain, sales in Portugal during the 12 months through March were 43 percent lower than in the full year 2007, and sales in Greece, Spain and Ireland were down by more than half. For the euro area as a whole, the decline was 26 percent.

By contrast, United States auto sales over the past 12 months were up 6 percent from a year earlier, and were only 3 percent below the 2007 level. In Britain, sales were up 12 percent on a year-over-year basis, and 2 percent below the 2007 level.

Source: European Automobile Manufacturers Association

Wednesday, April 16, 2014

The End of Our Financial Illusions

DESCRIPTION

Simon Johnson, former chief economist of the International Monetary Fund, is the Ronald A. Kurtz professor of entrepreneurship at the M.I.T. Sloan School of Management and co-author of “White House Burning: The Founding Fathers, Our National Debt, and Why It Matters to You.”

The global financial crisis that broke out following the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008 was a big shock. This is literally true in terms of the impact on investors and market prices; a wide range of financial variables moved rapidly in unexpected and worrying directions. But what happened was also a shock to the realm of ideas about finance.

Before September 2008 â€" or at least before 2007, when some of the underlying problems first became more clearly manifest â€" the prevailing consensus among officials and specialists was that financial innovation was a good thing. In isolated instances, a particular new product might not work out as planned, as happens, for example, with medical innovation. But over all, the consensus went, financial innovation led by the private sector was making the system safer and more efficient.

This view was wrong.

In its day, this line of thinking justified the legal and regulatory changes that allowed some banks to become very large and to build up a much more complex range of activities in the 1990s and early 2000s, including through various kinds of opaque derivatives transactions.

In retrospect, much of the financial innovation in the previous decades built up risk for the financial system in ways that were not properly understood by regulators or, arguably, by management at some of the largest banks.

Of course, some bankers knew exactly what they were doing as their companies increased their debt relative to their equity. On average, large complex global banks had about 2 percent equity and 98 percent debt on the liability side of the balance sheet before the crisis, meaning they were leveraged 50:1 (the ratio of total assets to equity).

The good news is that the official consensus was shattered in 2008, and is not coming back. Systemic risk slapped everyone in the face with an undeniable wake-up call.

However, the process of reforming the financial system is still at an early stage. The Dodd-Frank financial reforms of 2010 represent a useful start â€" including the Volcker Rule‘s restrictions on excessive risk-taking â€" and the recently adopted Basel III framework for capital regulation nudges equity requirements higher.

But the world’s largest banks will, by one informed estimate, end up â€" as things currently stand â€" with about 3 percent equity and 97 percent debt as the average structure of their balance sheet liabilities. In the United States, if the latest leverage rule is implemented and enforced properly, this will become 5 percent equity and 95 percent debt for the biggest eight banks by 2018. While 20:1 is better than 50:1, this is still not enough equity to assure a reasonable degree of financial stability in the foreseeable future.

The argument about finance has now shifted and is much more about whether capital requirements for the largest banks should be increased further. Those opposed to such a move offer three reasons why big banks should not be required to fund themselves with much more equity.

First, some people contend that the crisis of 2008 was a rare accident and Dodd-Frank fixed whatever problems existed. This is completely unconvincing â€" particularly because many of the same people have spent much of the last four years opposing and delaying financial reform.

Most importantly, it ignores the ways in which incentives and rules have changed since the 1980s. As James Kwak and I asserted in “13 Bankers,” the structure of the financial system is quite different now from what it was in 1980. In particular, the largest banks have become much bigger and more able to take on (and mismanage) much more risk.

The second argument is that the costs of the crisis were not huge, so there is no reason to fear a repeat. This is the view sometimes associated with former Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner. (Mr. Geithner has a book coming out soon, and it will be interesting to see his current position on this point).

But the impact of any financial crisis is not measured primarily in terms of whether the Treasury made or lost money on specific investments. The criteria instead should be what happened to output and jobs, as well as what the impact was on the country’s fiscal accounts. How much more public debt do we have now relative to what we had before â€" and what kind of lasting negative effects will that have?

Mr. Kwak and I took this on in “White House Burning,” putting the recent surge in public debt in the longer-run context of American fiscal policy. No matter how you look at it, the financial crisis was a complete disaster for the real economy and, given the way fiscal politics work in the modern United States, for the budget and for investments in any kind of physical infrastructure and education.

The third counterargument is that large complex financial institutions are needed because they provide some sort of magic for the broader economy. This still seems to be the view of some people at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, which recently published a set of research papers on the topic.

But the benefits they find are small relative to the potential costs. Anat Admati and Martin Hellwig’s “The Bankers’ New Clothes” makes the vulnerability of modern banking abundantly clear.

A recent report from the International Monetary Fund finds that the United States and other governments are providing large implicit subsidies to these big banks: The prospect of potential government support lowers their funding costs by about 100 basis points (one percentage point).

Many people are involved in the official sector’s rethinking of finance. This is the lasting contribution from books such as Sheila Bair’s “Bull by the Horns,” Neil Barofsky’s “Bailout” and Jeff Connaughton’s “The Payoff.” In government circles, key decision makers were swayed by officials including Thomas Hoenig and Jeremiah Norton (both of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation) and Sarah Bloom Raskin (then on the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; now at the Treasury Department). As chairman of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission, Gary Gensler had an immensely positive impact, both directly on the regulation of derivatives and also more broadly.

The Democratic senators Sherrod Brown of Ohio, Jeff Merkley of Oregon and Carl Levin of Michigan and Ted Kaufman of Delaware (who has since left the Senate), along with David Vitter, Republican of Louisiana, played key roles in shifting opinion. Elizabeth Warren’s work, both before and after her election to the Senate from Massachusetts, has also had great influence.

Of all the civil society organizations seeking to promote financial stability, Dennis Kelleher’s Better Markets stands out for its major impact through a relentless surge of arguments, comment letters and research. Its report on the cost of the crisis made clear beyond any reasonable doubt that the crisis had profound negative consequences for millions of people.

Many other officials have also shifted their views in important ways. We are not going back to the old ways of thinking about finance, and allowing for changes in these theories is an essential part of any modern economy. Finance needs to be regulated effectively, and large banks should fund themselves with much more equity than is currently the case.



Tuesday, April 15, 2014

On Tax Day: What’s Fair?

Jared Bernstein is a senior fellow at the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities in Washington and a former chief economist to Vice President Joseph R. Biden Jr.

Tax day is upon us and with it comes a lot of buzz about tax fairness.  That’s a broad concept, for sure, with many different meanings.  One of its meanings has been quantified as the share of taxes paid by various income groups. And that leads to claims of unfairness over the alleged disproportionate share of taxes paid by those at the top of the income scale.

For example, The Wall Street Journal cites the Tax Policy Center’s findings that “overall federal tax receipts from the top 1 percent of earners rose by 1.3 percentage points to 29.3 percent of all federal tax revenue.”  Meanwhile, the center’s data show that middle-income families’ tax share is around 10 percent.

If that sounds unfair, consider the following: The taxpayers whose liabilities and share of total taxes paid are going up also happen to be pretty much the only people whose incomes have been rising.  Certainly another dimension of fairness, especially in a progressive tax system within an increasingly unequal income distribution, is assigning the burden to those who’ve made the gains, especially when they’re such a small group.

There is considerable evidence to support this case.

- The inequality expert and Berkeley professor Emmanuel Saez recently wrote that from 2009 to 20012, the “top 1 percent incomes grew by 31.4 percent while bottom 99 percent incomes grew only by 0.4 percent.” He noted that “the top 1 percent captured 95 percent of the income gains in the first three years of the recovery.”

- As The New York Times pointed out Sunday, “the median compensation of a chief executive in 2013 was $13.9 million, up 9 percent from 2012.”  Bureau of Labor Statistics data show that median weekly earnings for regular old full-time workers â€" not those from the executive suites, but making around $40,000 a year â€" rose about 1 percent last year. After inflation â€" about 1.5 percent â€" they actually fell behind.

- Over the recovery, which began in mid-2009, G.D.P. is up 11 percent, corporate profits are up 50 percent, the S&P 500 is up almost 80 percent, and median household income is down 3 percent (all changes inflation adjusted).

Now, to be clear and fair, there are other factors to be considered.  First, while the rich appear to have largely recovered from the downturn and are once again speeding ahead of the rest, they did get severely whacked by it.  The most comprehensive data on this  â€" the Congressional Budget Office’s household data series â€" shows real, pretax losses by the top 1 percent of 26 percent from 2007 to 2010 (the most recent year for this series), as the financial implosion led to large capital losses.

But even in these data, from 2009 to 2010, the average income of the top 1 percent rose 16 percent, or about $200,000 (from $1.2 million to $1.4 million). Middle incomes rose a mere 0.3 percent, up $200, to $65,400.  So, in that year, the gain in pretax income to the wealthiest households was about three time the level of middle-class incomes.

Second, the only recent federal tax increases legislated, those from the fiscal cliff deal at the end of 2012, raised taxes solely on the wealthy.  That said, the tax deal also locked in 82 percent of the sweeping Bush tax cuts. That’s one reason we’re collecting less revenue than we will need to in order to meet our longer term fiscal challenges.

Like I said, there are lots of ways to measure fairness in the tax code, but one pretty intuitive measure, especially in a progressive system, is the share of taxes paid by each income group compared with their share of pretax income. Thankfully, the excellent analysts at Citizens for Tax Justice present that very comparison, and even better, they do so including all levels of taxation: federal, state, and local.

Most of the bars are about of equal height for each income group, implying all-in tax shares are about the same of income shares.  At least by this metric, one I think most would view as reasonable, tax shares seem broadly fair.  And given where all the growth has been going, along with stagnating middle and low pretax incomes, even more progressive tax changes may be fairly envisioned.

However, over the longer term, we cannot sustain our revenue needs solely by increasing the tax liabilities of those at the very top of the income scale. The United States remains a low-tax country and if incomes would only start growing more broadly, it would be reasonable, in the interest of meeting future fiscal challenges, to raise more revenue from more households.  The alternative, of course, would be large spending cuts in social insurance, public goods, defense, and nondefense programs across the board, cuts the majority of the public does not want, for good reason.



How Working Women Help the Economy

If someone asked you to name the most important economic trends of the last 30 years, you would probably respond with rising inequality, increasing globalization and fast-paced technological change.

But there’s another trend that has led to sharply higher economic output, and one that goes largely overlooked. That is the flood of women into the full-time workforce: Since 1979, the proportion of working-age women with a full-time job has surged to 40.7 percent from 28.6 percent. For mothers, the effect is even more striking: The proportion has climbed to 44.1 percent from 27.3 percent.

Those statistics come from a new report from the Center for American Progress, a left-of-center Washington-based research group. It finds that if women’s employment patterns had remained unchanged for the last three decades, the economy would be about 11 percent smaller, translating into $1.7 trillion in lost economic output in 2012, roughly equivalent to government spending on Social Security, Medicare and Medicaid.

The report also looks at the hours women worked, regardless of whether they were in full-time or part-time jobs. The median number of hours worked by women has climbed by 739 hours a year, to 1,664 hours; for mothers, hours worked has increased by 960 hours to 1,560.

The ultimate effects are richer families and a larger economy. Compare the United States to Japan, for instance. Tokyo has failed to jolt the Japanese economy out a generation-long slump, and the failure of the country to integrate women into the workforce is a major cause, according to researchers at institutions including the International Monetary Fund.

For cultural and economic reasons - Japan has a yawning gender pay gap - many Japanese women choose not to work. The female employment rate is 25 percentage points lower than the male employment rate, versus 14 percentage points in the United States and 5.7 percentage points in Sweden.

The United States could be yet stronger if more women worked, the authors of the Center for American Progress paper say. But there remain structural reasons that so many women stay home. Right now, about a third of all women and one quarter of all mothers do not work, they said.

Policies that would help women include regulations to foster greater flexibility in hours, mandatory paid family and medical leave and mandatory paid sick days that could be used to care for a child, they argue. “Even as mothers and women are making significant contributions to the U.S. economy, they continue to do so within a set of institutions that too often do not provide them with the kind of support that they need to do this successfully both at work and at home,” the authors write.



Sunday, April 13, 2014

Equal Opportunity and Social Innovation: Obama’s Policy Agenda

DESCRIPTION DESCRIPTION

Laura D’Andrea Tyson is a professor at the Haas School of Business at the University of California, Berkeley, and headed the Council of Economic Advisers and the National Economic Council under President Bill Clinton. Jonathan Greenblatt is a special assistant to President Obama and director of the Office of Social Innovation and Civic Participation at the White House.

As Thomas Piketty reminds us in his new book, “Capital in the 21st Century,” we are living in an era of rising inequality of income and wealth and of eroding equality of opportunity. In the United States, income and wealth inequality have reached levels not seen since the 1920s.  Perhaps the most glaring signs of the pernicious effects of inequality are the large and increasing gaps in educational attainment between the children of middle-income and low-income families. Demographic trends and job-displacing technological change are aggravating the social and economic maladies rooted in widening inequality.

President Obama has set forth an ambitious agenda to expand opportunity for all Americans, including health care reform, investment in education, an expansion of the earned-income tax credit and an increase in the minimum wage. However, as a result of budgetary constraints, federal  government financing for nonmilitary discretionary programs â€" a category that includes most federal support for research and for kindergarten through 12th grade and early childhood education â€" is on course to be lower in real terms than before the Great Recession.

Despite the long-term fiscal challenges, the federal government is still seeking to achieve better outcomes from policies designed to address social challenges. But it will have to provide stronger incentives for the private sector to develop and expand programs with the same objectives.  And it will need to create conditions to support the nonprofit organizations that increasingly are asked to deliver essential human services as the government pulls back even as their resources fail to keep pace with growing demand.

In response to these challenges, President Obama created the White House Office of Social Innovation and Civic Participation in early 2009.  He recognized that to deliver on the promise of opportunity for all Americans, the government must identify and invest in innovative solutions to social challenges and work with the private sector â€" nonprofits, the business community and investors seeking both social and financial goals â€" to develop and finance these solutions. The office set out to bring different groups into the policy making process to determine which programs get the best bang for taxpayers’ bucks, to tap new resources and scale what works and to develop market-based models to sustain successful programs.

Among its first efforts to invest in what works, the office established the Social Innovation Fund. The fund embodies the administration’s approach to addressing escalating social challenges at a time of inadequate federal financing. It works through intermediaries and partners with the private sector to amplify the impact of federal resources. The fund makes grants to social sector intermediaries like foundations, nonprofits and social enterprises on a competitive basis. It requires up to a three-to-one match of private money with government dollars.

The intermediaries are responsible for investing in nonprofits that try to create and expand effective programs. Funding over the life of a grant largely depends on evidence of success, much as venture capitalists invest in the early round of a start-up but maintain financing in further rounds only if the start-up shows success. To date, the fund has awarded over $175 million in grants, catalyzing more than $420 million in additional private philanthropic capital. More than 200 organizations have received money. The fund and its financing model enjoy bipartisan support in the Senate. The 2014 omnibus budget increased financing for the fund to $70 million, the highest level in its five-year history, from $47 million.

While the fund focuses on building capacity and financing nonprofits’ efforts, the $1 billion Small Business Investment Company Impact Fund, created by the Small Business Administration in 2010, focuses on fostering new venture funds whose investors seek both financial and social returns. The Small Business Administration provides up to a two-to-one match to private capital raised by these funds to invest in new businesses in underserved communities and areas like education and clean energy. To date, the small business fund has funneled $176 million in investment toward a dozen companies in California and Michigan. Applications for new investment money are pending as private sector interest in this kind of investing is gaining momentum.

Consistent with the goal of investing in what works, the administration has also pioneered Pay for Success financing to promote and expand social innovation. In a Pay for Success contract, sometimes called a social impact bond, the government sets a specific measurable target for a program to address a particular social goal â€" for example, reducing recidivism among juvenile offenders or providing early childhood education for vulnerable populations â€" and attracts an investor to pay for the program. The investor does so, lured by the promise of repayment of principal if the program meets the target and a higher return if the program exceeds the target. The investor gets no payback if the program fails to deliver results.

These contracts offer a win-win approach to their participants:  The nonprofit secures a new source of money for a program to address a social challenge; the investor can earn a return but bears the risk; and the government pays only for success. Moreover, payment by the government is intended to come from the savings generated by the program’s success.

In fall 2011, President Obama gathered state and city officials to brainstorm about the most promising applications of the pay for success model in the United States. Since then, nearly $50 million has been invested in these kinds of  transactions in Massachusetts, New York and Utah, and there is rising bipartisan interest in this model at all levels of government across the country.

At the federal level, the Obama administration proposed more than $80 million in its fiscal 2015 federal budget for these kinds of pilot programs in several federal agencies to encourage policy innovations in areas like juvenile justice, work force development and educational achievement.

More significantly, the administration has proposed a $300 million Pay for Success Incentive Fund to be housed in the Treasury Department. This fund would provide state and local governments with federal matching money for programs that produce federal budget savings. This fund would also offer a way to reduce the risk of these transactions to state and local governments, nonprofits and investors to encourage them to experiment with this approach and attract private capital for the upfront financing.

The hope is that this fund could do for “outcome financing” what the Community Development Financial Institutions Fund did for community finance 20 years ago. At that time, poor communities lacked access to private capital from both nonprofit institutions and banks. Yet, by 2013, the C.D.F.I. Fund supported more than 800 such certified financial institutions that made over 24,000 loans and investments, totaling almost $2 billion. In aggregate, these institutions manage more than $50 billion in assets and provide loans to nonprofits and small businesses that serve low-income populations and communities. If the Pay for Success Incentive Fund had a similar impact, it would mobilize private capital to finance and expand effective social programs, with benefits for vulnerable populations, risk-taking investors and the general public.

The United States is not alone in this approach. For example, Britain established a global Task Force on Social Impact Investing before the 2013 meeting of the Group of 8 industrialized countries in London. The United States is a member of the task force, which is expected to make recommendations this fall. Such initiatives offer considerable promise for addressing social challenges at a time of constrained government budgets and rising inequality.



Friday, April 11, 2014

Help for the Big Guys

Even those among us who are doing the best can use a little help now and then.

For the year 2011, the Internal Revenue Service reports, there were 30,604 tax returns filed that showed adjusted gross income of at least $5 million. Of those, 117, or 0.38 percent, reported that the income included unemployment compensation.

That ratio turns out to be the lowest in three years. In 2010, 143, or 0.50 percent, of the 28,791 returns showing income of at least $5 million included unemployment compensation. In 2009, the figures were 92, or 0.40 percent, of 23,026 returns; in 2008, 99, or 0.28 percent, of 34,870 returns.

The number of returns showing income of at least $5 million remained well below the record of 46,484 set in 2007. That year, there were so few high-income returns with unemployment compensation that the government did not reveal the numbers, for fear of identifying specific taxpayers.

How, you might ask, could anyone making that much money qualify for unemployment compensation?

One answer is that most or all of the income might be from investments. Another is that even wealthy Wall Streeters can get laid off. (It would be interesting to know how many of the 99 in 2008 worked for Lehman Brothers.) And, of course, many of these returns were filed jointly. One spouse could have been laid off even as the other did very well.

Over all, the number of 2011 tax returns that included unemployment compensation fell 12 percent from 2010, to 13.2 million. In 2007, before the Great Recession, the figure was 7.6 million.



The Great Moderation Is Back

Perhaps you remember the Great Moderation, the comforting term economists pinned on the period of relatively steady growth that began in the early 1980s.

Perhaps you’ve even looked back and laughed at the very idea.

Jason Furman has a more complicated view. The head of the president’s Council of Economic Advisers argued in an interesting speech on Thursday that the Great Moderation is still in progress. The growth of jobs and economic activity over the last five years has snapped back into the same kind of steady pattern that prevailed before the recession, a pattern documented in the chart below.

Including the Great Recession does not change the basic pattern. Economic volatility, on average, is still lower now than in earlier decades.

Source: Jason Furman

This is a hollow victory for those who championed the idea of a Great Moderation. They saw the trend as evidence that the economy was less likely to experience a dramatic downturn. Mr. Furman is essentially arguing that those economists were right in describing the phenomenon, but not its implications.

“The Great Recession certainly does reveal serious limitations of the concept of a Great Moderation,” he said. “After all, there is no sense in which the recession itself â€" which witnessed the largest peak-to-trough downturn in G.D.P. on record â€" was indicative of a more stable economy than in the 1950s or 1960s.”

The Great Moderation, in other words, is not a justification for complacency.

Mr. Furman also sees new reasons to doubt some of the standard explanations offered before the recession for the greater stability of growth.

One explanation held that economic shocks had become less frequent, but Mr. Furman noted that there has been no shortage of them in recent years: “This list includes international events like the European sovereign debt crisis, the tsunami and nuclear accident in Japan, and the disruption of Libya’s oil supply. It includes extreme weather like Hurricane Sandy and the 2012 drought that was described by the U.S.D.A. as the ‘most severe and extensive drought in at least 25 years.’ And of course, it includes an unnecessary and unprecedented degree of brinksmanship in Congress’s handling of federal fiscal policy, culminating in the 16-day shutdown last October.”

Those shocks have not shaken the basic stability of growth, although Mr. Furman noted the disconcerting possibility that the impact was simply delayed.

Another view attributed the stability of consumer spending to the increased availability of credit, but consumer spending in recent years has remained surprisingly steady despite constraints on the availability of loans.

Mr. Furman gave greater credence to the view that monetary policy has helped, by stabilizing inflation expectations and curtailing the Great Recession. He did not offer a complete explanation, instead recommending additional research.



Thursday, April 10, 2014

Congress and the Belief That Human Life Is Priceless

DESCRIPTION

Uwe E. Reinhardt is an economics professor at Princeton. He has some financial interests in the health care field.

The stern grilling administered recently by members of Congress to Mary Barra, the chief executive of General Motors took me back to March 2009, when I had the privilege of testifying at a hearing before the House Energy and Commerce Subcommittee on Health.

At that hearing, Representative Phil Gingrey, M.D. and Republican of Georgia, took me behind the woodshed over a remark I had made in a post on this blog. I had called the idea that human life is priceless both romantic and silly.

Representative Gingrey asked me:

Dr. Reinhardt, do you believe that we, as individuals, in America should have the ability to value our own lives, or is this something we should ask the government to do for us, i.e., ration that care when you get to be 90 years old and you need a hip replacement, do you just let them fall and break the hip and die of pneumonia? Or do they get the opportunity, if they value that, to get that hip replaced?

I responded that the issue is not the monetary value we put on our own lives with our own money, but rather that those who preside over private and public health insurance funds, Congress included, at some point have to ask themselves at what price they can afford to buy additional life years for people insured with those collectively financed funds, which are, after all, finite.

Mr. Gingrey’s riposte was that I spoke “like a German philosopher of yesterday.” I deemed that a cheap shot.

Indeed, as a professor of economics I would like to assign Representative Gingrey and his like-minded colleagues on the Hill to watch an instructive video clip of an exchange on the value of human life between the late Nobel Laureate Milton Friedman and a college student.

In that exchange the student objected to a decision by Ford Motor, based on a formal benefit-cost analysis, not to spend $11 a car on changing a design that had placed the gas tank in the subcompact Pinto, built during the 1970s, in a way that increased the likelihood of gas-tank explosions. (For details on that case, see this paper).

Mr. Friedman contended that the student’s complaint merely was over the low value - $200,000 per life lost - that the company had placed on avoiding fatalities and serious burn injuries from the safety hazard - not over the principle that the value of human life has a finite upper limit.

The student actually seemed to agree to that principle, but he recoiled at the idea - alas, not very articulately- that some unknown person within Ford could blithely assume on behalf of all Pinto buyers that the value of avoiding a horrible death or injury from a burning Pinto was as low as the company had assumed in its formal risk analysis.

The student’s intuition seems to have been that most of these owners would have been willing to pay the extra $11 for the fix to the gas-tank problem, an intuition many readers may share. The practical challenge is how one would retrieve such information from current and prospective owners of a car. For that reason, benefit-cost analysts use an assumed value of life, as best they can infer it from the relevant research literature. From what I know of that literature, $200,000 per life actually is low.

The Pinto case has a strong resemblance to the current uproar over General Motors’ handling of a faulty ignition key in certain models built in the past decade.

In harshly querying Ms. Marra, Senator Barbara Boxer, Democrat of California, referred to the now famous memorandum “Value Analysis of Auto Fuel Fed Fire Related Fatalities” written by Edward Ivey, then a G.M. engineer, in 1973, in which he set forth an explicit benefit-cost analysis on a safety issue in certain G.M. cars in that era.

In that memorandum the value of a fatality (i.e., a human life lost) as a result of a fuel-fed fire hazard in the cars was put at $200,000, although Mr. Ivey hastens to caution readers, “It is really impossible to put a value on human life.” The Ivey memo subsequently featured in a law suit, settled in 1999, that ultimately cost G.M. $1.2 billion.

In their public appearances, on the campaign trail or at hearings, members of Congress may find it useful to pretend that they deem human life priceless. It can explain, for example, why Congress refuses to allow considerations of costs - what is called “cost-effectiveness analysis” â€" to be pursued by the federally funded Patient Centered Outcomes Research Institute that was authorized by Congress in 2010.

But as a legislative body, Congress routinely, albeit implicitly, puts finite prices on human lives in the trade-offs members make during budget votes. They may forbid cost-effectiveness analysis for coverage decisions under Medicare, but they implicitly price out human life as finite at the margins of their budget allocations - for example, in budget cuts on health programs for the poor.

Congress also implicitly puts prices on human life when it foists upon the Pentagon expensive weapons systems of dubious effectiveness that please cash-carrying lobbyists, retired generals now fronting for military contractors and constituents in districts where the weapons systems are manufactured.

In giving in to those entreaties, however, Congress may leave the Pentagon to send America’s forces into battle without adequate body armor or properly armored vehicles and even without sufficient troops to guard ammunition dumps left behind by the defeated enemy - literally as free weapons supermarkets for insurgents. All of this happened in Iraq.

I recall sitting at dinner with a group officers of the United States Marine Corps in 2004, about to return with their platoons to Iraq, there to protect truck convoys. The young officers were wondering how they might affix sandbags to the doors of their platoons’ Humvees to stop shrapnel from roadside improvised explosive devices tearing through the flimsy doors of those vehicles.

As the father of one of those officers, I was not well pleased during those Congressional hearings in 2009 to be condescendingly lectured by a member of Congress on the value of human life and to have my view on that matter, which is shared by literally every American economist, written off as that of a “German philosopher of yesterday” â€" most probably meant as an allusion to Nazi ideology.

Mr. Gingrey and his colleagues on the Hill would be well advised to take a look at that above-cited exchange between that student and Mr. Friedman. Upon serious reflection, they might agree with Mr. Friedman.

In a future post, I shall describe how economists try to infer the value Americans implicitly put on human life in their daily decisions and what values have been found in empirical research.



Wednesday, April 9, 2014

Heroes of Banking Reform

DESCRIPTION

Simon Johnson, former chief economist of the International Monetary Fund, is the Ronald A. Kurtz professor of entrepreneurship at the M.I.T. Sloan School of Management and co-author of “White House Burning: The Founding Fathers, Our National Debt, and Why It Matters to You.”

In the mid-2000s, Sheila Bair, then the chairwoman of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, fought to retain a rule that would limit the amount of leverage, i.e., the amount that could be borrowed, particularly by the largest American financial companies. Among her most difficult opponents were key people at the Federal Reserve and most of the international community involved with bank regulation. (The details are in Chapter 3 of her book, “Bull by the Horns.”)

The financial crisis made a big difference. Ms. Bair was proved right. Her critics in the United States and in Europe had insisted that a sophisticated “risk-weighted” approach to measuring the adequacy of bank equity capital would suffice. But the risk-weights used, by regulators and the industry, proved repeatedly wrong. Complex derivatives based on mortgage-backed securities and European sovereign debt were rated as AAA (the safest possible); both turned out instead to be highly risky and prone to fall rapidly in value.

This week, Ms. Bair and the people who agree with her on the need to restrict leverage at our largest banks won a major victory.

In the 18th or 19th century, a victory on this scale would have been become clear in flowery speeches or perhaps an act of Congress. We live in an age of specialists and complex terminology, so this week’s victory was appropriately enough wrapped in technical language of modern bank regulation.

The new rule is the “supplementary leverage ratio,” and it limits how much the largest banks can borrow relative to their overall assets. You need “more than $700 billion in consolidated total assets” or “more than $10 trillion in assets under custody” in order to be covered by this rule. (The link above is to the summary news release; the full rule is 54 pages long.)

By 2018, the eight largest financial companies will need to fund their overall activities with at least 5 percent equity (so they can still have up to 95 percent debt, relative to their total balance sheet size).

As the Fed puts it, in official-speak, “A perception persists in the markets that some companies remain ‘too big to fail,’ posing an ongoing threat to the financial system.”

Thomas M. Hoenig, vice chairman of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, former president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City and a longstanding proponent of more effective capital regulation, issued a clear and powerful statement regarding why leverage should be limited in this way: “Banks with stronger capital positions are in a better position to lend, to compete favorably in any market and to achieve satisfactory results for investors. Without sufficient capital, the opposite is true.”

Opinion in official circles more broadly has shifted, in part because of strenuous efforts by some individuals.

Mr. Hoenig, for example, has long argued for more emphasis on the leverage ratio:

For example, in the period 2006-8, there was no binding leverage ratio on the largest institutions. It is evident now that during that period banks increased their leverage and took on excessive risks to meet targeted returns. It was the reliance on and manipulation of a risk-based capital framework that allowed risk to build up to a point that nearly brought the global financial system to collapse.

Banks with more equity capital (meaning less leverage) were better able to sustain credit than banks that were in danger of becoming insolvent (i.e., having their equity wiped out by large losses.)

These new rules represent a vindication for Ms. Bair, Mr. Hoenig and others who have played a leadership role on this topic, including Jeremiah Norton, a member of the board at the F.D.I.C. (see his statement this week). I’m a member of the independent and nonpartisan Systemic Risk Council, founded and led by Ms. Bair, and we have also written comment letters urging higher capital requirements.

While this aspect of the broader debate on financial stability is not over, people who argue in favor of even stronger capital requirements are increasingly gaining the upper hand. (For an entertaining and insightful analysis of the current academic debate, see this paper by Paul Pfleiderer.)

The consensus among officials is shifting. Perhaps not enough and definitely not fast enough, but it is definitely moving in the right direction.

As Mr. Hoenig says at the end of his statement,

I am confident that supervisors will rely increasingly on the leverage ratio, as the market already does, to judge a firm’s capital levels, loss absorbing capacity and balance sheet strength.



Tuesday, April 8, 2014

The Power of Sebelius

DESCRIPTION

Casey B. Mulligan is an economics professor at the University of Chicago. He is the author of “The Redistribution Recession: How Labor Market Distortions Contracted the Economy.”

In setting the 2015 calendar parameters for health plans and employers, Kathleen Sebelius, the secretary of health and human services, quietly did some creative but questionable arithmetic that forced taxpayers to give still more help to businesses and people who buy health insurance.

The Affordable Care Act is designed to encourage people to enroll in a health insurance plan and to shop around for value for their medical dollars.

On the first point, the law says large employers will be charged a penalty for not providing coverage to their full-time employees (and thereby helping their employees get taxpayer-subsidized coverage). The amount of the penalty was set to be economically significant relative to the costs of coverage.

On the second point, people enrolled in health plans are asked to pay part of their medical expenses - “cost-sharing,” as the law calls it. This is why the plans sold on healthcare.gov have high deductibles in comparison with traditional employer plans. The amount that plan participants are supposed to pay is supposed to be commensurate with the costs of medical care.

To achieve both of these goals, the law specifies that the cost-sharing rules and the employer penalty be indexed to health cost inflation. Specifically, the Affordable Care Act says that in each year after 2014, the employer penalty and cost-sharing parameters will exceed the value they have in 2014 by a percentage equal to the “premium adjustment percentage,” which is “the percentage (if any) by which the average per capita premium for health insurance coverage in the United States for the preceding calendar year (as estimated by the secretary no later than Oct. 1 of such preceding calendar year) exceeds such average per capita premium for 2013 (as determined by the secretary).” The “secretary” refers to the secretary of the Department of Health and Human Services, currently Ms. Sebelius.

The average per capita premium for health insurance coverage increased in 2013, especially in the individual market, because the Affordable Care Act required plans to provide more benefits. For example, the eHealth price index was about 40 percent greater during the first quarter of 2014 than it was for calendar year 2013 (see this chart, in which the dotted red line is the 2013 average). This is no surprise - more benefits mean higher premiums - and I presume that Congress understood this.

This is not to say that high-premium high-benefit plans are undesirable, just that, without subsidies, you get what you pay for, and pay for what you get.

But a political problem arises in that a premium increase that averages, say, 40 percent would require a 40 percent increase in the caps on what individuals with coverage can be asked to pay for their own medical expenses and increase the employer penalty by 40 percent (above what it would have been had it been enforced in 2014).

Among other things, the salary equivalent of the employer penalty next year, with a 40 percent premium adjustment percentage, would be almost $4,300 per employee per year.

To make matters (politically) worse, the increase in premiums from 2013 to 2014 is likely to be permanent, because the new rules on minimum benefits are permanent (as the law now stands). In other words, an increase in caps and penalties next year would be likely to last long into the future. The Department of Health and Human Services needed a way to measure the average premium for health insurance without acknowledging what is actually happening to health insurance premiums.

The department explains the two principles behind its solution. The first principle is to estimate premiums with its own projections, rather than averaging actual premiums observed in the marketplace. The second principle is to limit its use of data to market segments where “the premium trend is more stable.”

Since only one year has passed since 2013, for now that means limiting the data used to market segments where the premium adjustments are sufficiently close to zero.

In particular, for now the premiums in the individual market will be ignored for the purposes of estimating changes in premiums. As a result, the secretary has declared that the premium adjustment percentage is but a fraction of 40 percent: 4.2 percent, when rounded off.

I am not saying that the premium adjustment percentage should have been 40, just that it should have been based on actual transactions in all of the market segments, and as a result significantly greater than 4.2.

Perhaps taxpayers of the future will remember March 11, 2014, as the day when one cabinet secretary added billions of dollars to the deficit.



Monday, April 7, 2014

After the Jobs Report, a Look at Three Critical Labor Market Trends

Jared Bernstein is a senior fellow at the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities in Washington and a former chief economist to Vice President Joseph R. Biden Jr.

In the aftermath of last week’s jobs report, there are three critical labor market trends that need to be examined more closely.

Reversing the Shrinking Labor Force. To my mind, the most important labor market question is how much can stronger growth repair the damage to the labor force participation rate.

There are two reasons that I give this question such primacy. The first one is micro: most people depend on their paycheck, not their portfolio, so absent a job or enough hours of work, their living standards will take a hit.

The second is macro. Overall economic growth is the sum of productivity growth and labor force growth. Less of the latter makes it harder to grow faster, creating a vicious cycle of weak GDP growth, weak job growth, and low labor force participation.

Some of the decline in the labor force, maybe a third to as much as half â€" is driven by older workers dropping out, but even that is not as benign as it sounds. As some people are healthier for longer, they’ve been extending their work force tenure in recent decades and thus it’s a mistake to assume that every older labor force dropout is happy to leave (though many surely are â€" let’s not fetishize work!).

At any rate, those of us concerned about these dynamics were happy to see the pop in the labor force participation rate last month, though of course no one should make a big deal out of one-month result like this.

Here, however, is an interesting and favorable trend. It’s from the labor force flows data, which tracks people’s monthly movements in and out of employment, unemployment, and not in-the-labor-force (or NILF; remember, if you’re looking for work, you’re unemployed; if you give up the search, you’re NILF). This line shows the share of the population moving from unemployment to NILF, and is thus a driver of the decline in the labor force.

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

It’s clearly a cyclical variable, as you’d expect, and it shot up in the great recession, as discouraged job seekers left the labor force. But while it is still elevated, its decline is quite sharp, a positive sign for restoring some labor force growth.

Increasing Job Growth. A quick point about the underlying pace of job growth:  The 192,000 jobs added in March is a solid number, but we’re still way behind where we need to be in terms of job quantity. Various commentators made a big deal of the fact that with last month’s gains, the level of private sector employment was finally back to its prerecession peak.

But all that means is that we’ve finally climbed out of the deep hole that the recession blew in the nation’s payrolls; it’s certainly not enough jobs to employ the growth in the working-age population over all that time. And we’re talking a long time here: It took more than six years just to repair the damage, compared with two, three and four years in the previous three recessions/recoveries. (Why it’s taking so much longer to regain lost jobs â€" why today’s recoveries tend to start out “jobless” â€" is another important question, beyond my present scope).

The figure below, using numbers developed by the economist Heidi Shierholz of the Economic Policy Institute, shows where we are compared with where we should be (the figure uses total payrolls, including government). The gap between the two lines last month amounts to over seven million jobs; that’s how many jobs short we are in the labor market once you adjust for the fact that just by dint of population growth, there are a lot more people who need work.

So sure, March posted decent job gains, and as the figure shows, we’re slowly catching up to the trend line. But the operative word there, especially for policy makers, is “slowly.”

Source: Heidi Shierholz, Economic Policy Institute

Raising Wages. We covered job quantity. What about job quality? There’s been a bit of noise lately about some acceleration in the growth of wages. The figure below shows annual growth rates for two nominal wage series for private sector workers â€" the overall average and lower paid workers â€" along with the core inflation measure most closely watched by the Federal Reserve.

Average wages have been growing at a relatively low rate of 2 percent and show little sign of any acceleration. The pace of wage growth for lower-wage workers has picked up a bit in recent months, but remains in the noninflationary 2 to 2.5 percent range.

Source: BLS, BEA; “core prices” is the core PCE deflator.

In fact, you can easily observe the validity of that assertion by comparing the wage trends to the price trends for the inflation measure most closely watched by the Federal Reserve, the core PCE deflator. Not only is wage growth not bleeding in price growth, but there’s a growing gap between the two. Important, inflationary expectations are also “well anchored” around 2 percent.

Too often in recent years, powerful forces yell “Inflation!” every time some working stiff sees a couple of months of real pay gains. For the Fed to listen to such Yellen (sorry…) would be a great way to ensure the continuance of the unbalanced returns to growth that have dominated this recovery so far.

So, putting it all together, the job market is slowly but steadily improving, it’s got a long way to go, and there are some tentative signs that labor market sideliners may be getting pulled back in. Wage growth is steady and nonthreatening, inflation-wise, and given how little growth in this recovery has flowed to paychecks as opposed to profits, it is essential that whatever bit of heat there is in the job market be fanned, not stamped out.



Sunday, April 6, 2014

The Front-Runners of Wall Street

Nancy Folbre, professor emerita at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst.

Nancy Folbre is professor emerita of economics at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst.

In the world of financial trading, a front-runner is someone who gains an unfair advantage with inside information, including access to a high-speed transaction network revealing specific trades other people are trying to make.

“Flash Boys,” Michael Lewis’s new nonfiction thriller, reveals the high-tech details of this largely invisible process. More important, it reveals the enabling policies of major Wall Street institutions that did little to discourage it.

Like the public bailout of major banks during the last financial crisis, tolerance of front-running challenges the faith that competition always guarantees efficient outcomes and the creed that market value accurately measures real contributions.

The book itself sticks to a heroic narrative driven by likable good guys who patiently decipher and partially remedy illegal practices. More bluntly, Mr. Lewis announced on “60 Minutes” last week that the stock market is rigged.

Some titans of the financial world, including Charles Schwab, founder of a well-known discount brokerage house, agree. Mr. Schwab describes the form of front-running practiced by high-speed frequency traders as a cancer undermining confidence in the free-enterprise system. Others, including Vanguard’s founder, John Bogle, insist that few investors have actually been hurt by front-running and that high-frequency trading has redeeming features, such as lowering transaction costs.

But in merit-based competition, a violation of the rules undermines the larger game regardless of how many individuals are directly harmed by it.

As the Naked Capitalism blog points out, front-running doesn’t rank very high on the scale of harm done by recent financial travesties. But this doesn’t imply that the “victimless crime” defense can fly.

A recent Bloomberg Businessweek article notes, “High-frequency trading doesn’t prey on small mom-and-pop investors.” True, but plenty of ordinary people have invested in large pension funds whose trades have been affected.

Imagine a similar defense of Lance Armstrong’s illegal use of performance-enhancing drugs in the Tour de France, which, after all, didn’t hurt a very large percentage of cyclists.

The same article protests, “High frequency traders aren’t Wall Street insiders.” Why should this matter? In any case, the real shocker in “Flash Boys” is not that a few naughty players game the system, but that the New York Stock Exchange and major investment banks help them do it.

Some assert that front-running is not taking place in high-frequency trading. Tell that to the Federal Bureau of Investigation, which opened an investigation of the practice a year ago.

Another jaded defense of front-running simply claims it was ever thus: “History shows that those trying to gain an advantage are simply good at adapting.” Since when is insider trading simply another form of adaptation?

With his adept efforts to market his book, Mr. Lewis has set off a debate over a theoretical point he never explicitly confronts: Intense competition doesn’t automatically elicit greater effort or excellent performance. In the absence of firm principles and strict rule enforcement, it elicits criminal behavior and lame rationalization.

In what the economists Robert Frank and Philip J. Cook call “The Winner Take-All Society,” honest losers are left behind.

The market is not an impersonal arbiter of economic value, and financial markets, in particular, sometimes reward malfeasance rather than merit.

Most of the approximately 165,200 employees in the securities industry in New York City are honest, hard-working individuals whose reputation has been tainted by the culture of Wall Street. It’s worth remembering, however, that last year they took home bonuses amounting to about $26.7 billion.

The Institute for Policy Studies estimates that this sum is more than enough to double the pay for all 1,085,000 Americans who work full time at the current federal minimum wage of $7.25 per hour. Most of them are honest, hard-working individuals whose ability to earn a living has been hampered by the decline of Main Street.

Yet Republicans in Congress continue to oppose a proposed increase to $10.10 an hour, which they consider undue interference in the labor market. They don’t like interference in financial markets, either. What they seem to like is races without rules.



Friday, April 4, 2014

The Good News in the Jobs Report — Sort Of

We’ve recovered! The country now has more private sector jobs than it did before the recession, surpassing its previous peak. That was in January 2008, when there were 115,977,000 jobs, according to the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ survey of businesses. Last month, the bureau announced Friday morning, there were 116,087,000. High fives all around.

Actually, no. Many of the comparisons of the pre- and post-recession economies leave out one significant detail: we’re not just trying to get back to where we were before the bottom dropped out. We’re trying to get back to where we would have been. Keep in mind that we have 15 million more people now than we did then, an increase of 4.6 percent.

Back then, the unemployment rate was 5 percent â€" now it is 6.7 percent. By the end of 2012, the Chicago Federal Reserve estimated, the country’s total payroll was about 6 million jobs below what it should have been. “Closing this gap by 2016, for instance, would require payroll employment growth of about 195,000 per month on average over the next four years,” the report said. So far, the average since the end of 2012 has been 194,000.

The good news in the report, by Daniel Aaronson and Scott Brave â€" sort of â€" is that fewer jobs will be required in the future because fewer people are participating in the labor force (either working or actively looking for work). They said that the economy would need only 80,000 jobs a month â€" far less than the 150,000 to 200,000 needed in the 1980s and 1990s, when millions of women were entering the labor force. In a couple of years, the number of jobs needed to stay on trend would fall to 35,000. That augurs a future of low growth. Another estimate, based on Congressional Budget Office projections, says 90,000 jobs a month are needed.

But, they acknowledge, that is based on a number of assumptions about which there is high uncertainty, such as the extent to which the decline in participation is driven by demographic changes like aging Baby Boomers, as opposed to discouraged people who would like to have jobs dropping out. Right now, there are 6.1 million people who are not in the labor force but “want a job now,” lower than last year’s average of 6.4 million. As the job market improves, those people tend to re-enter the labor force.



It’s Still Bad for the Long-Term Unemployed

At first blush, it’s great news. The number of long-term unemployed Americans - meaning those out of a job for more than six months - has dropped to 3.7 million in March from a high of 6.8 million in April 2010. The ranks of the long-term jobless have plummeted by 837,000 over the past year alone, helping to drive down the unemployment rate.

But not so fast. The labor market has largely normalized in terms of short-term unemployment. But it gets worse and worse the longer you’ve been out of a job. As the chart that ran with a story I wrote today shows, short-term joblessness is actually well below its 2007 level. Long-term joblessness is still more than twice as high.

So what’s happening to the long-term unemployed? Well, some of them are getting jobs. The problem is that often those jobs are part-time, or pay far less than the ones that workers had before. About 7.4 million Americans - up from 7.2 million as of November - are working part-time but would like to be working full-time.

And new research by Alan B. Krueger, the former chairman of President Obama’s Council of Economic Advisers, and his co-authors shows that only one in 10 workers who counted themselves as long-term jobless in a given month between 2008 and 2012 had a full-time gig a year later.

The federal government is offering less and less help to the long-term jobless. In January, an emergency program that pushed the maximum duration of jobless benefits up to as many as 73 weeks expired. Now, in most states, the maximum duration of payments is 26 weeks. Once those payments run out - along with the government requirement that a worker be looking for a job while receiving them - many among the long-term jobless accept a crummy job or simply give up.

The evidence remains that the so-so recovery is not enough to help the long-term jobless. “In some ways, the job market is tougher now than in any recession,” said Janet L. Yellen, the chairman of the Federal Reserve, in a speech this week. “These workers find it exceptionally hard to find steady, regular work, and they appear to be at a severe competitive disadvantage when trying to find a job. The concern is that the long-term unemployed may remain on the sidelines, ultimately dropping out of the workforce.”

But she gave one glimmer of hope: that a faster recovery would help the long-term jobless, if it would only speed up.